BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales High Court (Chancery Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales High Court (Chancery Division) Decisions >> HM Inspector of Taxes v Citibank Investments Ltd. [2000] EWHC Ch 451 (02 November 2000) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWHC/Ch/2000/451.html Cite as: [2000] EWHC Ch 451 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
CHANCERY DIVISION
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
____________________
Griffin (Her Majesty's Inspector of Taxes) |
Appellant |
|
and |
||
Citibank Investments Limited |
Respondent |
____________________
Mr C McCall QC and Mr M Furness QC instructed by Solicitors of Inland Revenue of Somerset House, London, WC2 for the Appellant
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
Mr Justice Patten:
Introduction
At the time relevant to this appeal section 128 of the 1998 Act provided as follows:
128. Commodity and financial futures etc.: losses and gains
Any gain arising to any person in the course of dealing in commodity or financial futures or in qualifying options, which., apart from this section would constitute profits or gains chargeable to tax under Schedule D otherwise than as the profits of a trade, shall not be chargeable to tax under that Schedule.
In this section "commodity or financial futures" and "qualifying options" have the same meaning as in section [143 of the 1992 Act]', and the reference to a gain arising in the course of dealing in commodity or financial futures includes any gain which is regarded as arising in the course of such dealing by virtue of subsection (3) of that section.
(b) "qualifying option" means a traded option or financial option as defined in Section 144(8).
(c) "financial option" means an option which is not a trade option, as defined in paragraph (b) above, but which……
(i) relates to currency, shares, securities or an interest rate and is granted (otherwise than as agent) by a member of a recognises stock exchange, by an authorised person within the meaning of the Financial Services Act 1986……
The principal facts found by the Special Commissioners are set out in paragraphs 13-33 of their decision and can be summarised as follows:
(1) CIL is a company within the Citibank group of companies. Its main function is to hold investments. Its activities are not taxable under Case 1 of Schedule D and the option transactions which are the subject of this appeal did not constitute trading transactions;
(2) CIP is another company within the Citibank group. It caries on the trade of a banker and dealer in financial instruments and is recognised as a writer of options under the provisions prescribed by ISDA of which CIP was a founder member. At all material times CIP was an authorised person within the meaning of the Financial Services Act 1986;
(3) ISDA (the International Swap Dealers Association Inc.) was established in 1984 with twelve members including CIP. In 1987 it published a Master Agreement and certain Definitions. These Definitions were revised and re-published in 1991. They were intended for use with agreements such as the ISDA Master Agreement and in confirmations of individual transactions governed by those agreements. The 1991 ISDA Definitions were produced as part of the documents on this appeal and it was common ground before me that they were designed for and routinely used as the standard terms and conditions of option agreements such as the ones under consideration;
(4) In February 1994 Citibank NA, a company in the Citibank group, took advice from Arthur Anderson about the corporation tax consequences of what was called the equity box structure. The purpose of the equity box structure, the circumstances leading up to the purchase of the two options, and the details of the contractual arrangements are set out by the Special Commissioners in paragraphs 17-33 of their decision and because they are relevant to a number of arguments addressed to me on this appeal I set them out in full:
17. In February 1994 Citibank NA, a company in the Citibank group, consulted a leading firm of chartered accountants about the corporation tax consequences of a proposed structure which was called the equity box structure. Under that structure any United Kingdom company would enter into a combination of transactions with Citibank in same-dated European equity linked options. (In this context the phrase "European options" means options which can only be exercised on one day (usually the last) of their term.) The combination of transactions proposed would enable the company to establish a known return on the exercise of the options, regardless of the actual movement in the underlying index. Because the return could be ascertained at the outset, Citibank could price the transactions as if they were a deposit of money.
The advice was that, although each case had to be judged on its own facts, a number of factors indicated that trading was not taking place and so capital treatment for tax purposes would be appropriate.
18. In December 1994 the Appellant received the sum of £150M as the result of the realisation of a substantial investment. As the money was not required until April 1996 (when certain borrowings had to be repaid) consideration was given as to how it might best be invested. At that time the Appellant had capital losses so there were advantages in receiving funds in the form of capital gains rather than as income liable to corporation tax.
19. In December 1994 a presentation was made to the Board of Directors of the Appellant describing the equity box structure which, it was said, would provide returns in the form of capital gains. The investment would be in two European options with the same inception and maturity dates. Both options would be linked to the FTSE 100 Share Index; one would be a capped call option and the other would be a floored put option. The effect of using these options in combination meant that there would always be a guaranteed payment of a predetermined amount when the options were exercised. An amount could, therefore, be agreed at the outset to reflect the appropriate rate for the period. If £150M were invested by the Appellant in December 1994, and if the transactions were effected with International under and ISDA Agreement, then in April 1996 there would be a return (of capital and uplift) amounting to £161.88M. It was an essential part of the equity box scheme that the standard ISDA documentation should be used for all transactions.
20. The presentation went on to discuss two other ways in which the £150M of surplus funds could be invested by the Appellant; these were the making of a deposit investment and the repayment of existing borrowings. The making of a deposit investment would mean that tax would be payable on the interest which meant that the net return would be £7.96M as compared with £11.88M for the equity box scheme. The repayment of existing borrowing would mean that tax relief would be foregone which would mean that the net return would be £9.37M as compared with £11.88M for the equity box scheme; penalty costs on prepayment of the borrowings would also have to be considered and these amounted to about £950,000.00.
21. After considering the presentation, on 16 December 1994 the Board of Directors of the Appellant resolved to purchase from International a call option linked to the FTSE 100 Index at a premium not exceeding £75M and a put option linked to the FTSE 100 Index at a premium not exceeding £85M and to confirm the purchase by the execution of trade confirmation documents.
The transactions – 29 December 1994
22. On 29 December 1994 International sent to the Appellant a document headed "OTC Equity Option Confirmation". ("OTC" means "over the counter"). The confirmation stated that it set forth the terms and conditions of the transaction entered into. It specifically provided that the definitions and provisions contained in the 1991 ISDA Definitions were incorporated in the confirmation. The confirmation went on to say that, if the Appellant and International were, or were to become, parties to a Master Agreement in the form published by ISDA, then the confirmation supplemented, formed part of, and was subject to such agreement. In this way the ISDA 1991 Definitions were made part of the agreement to be entered into by the Appellant and International.
23. On 11 April 1995 the Appellant and International did enter into a Master Agreement (the Agreement) in the form published by ISDA in 1992. The agreement was stated to be effective from 29 December 1994 and, at the hearing, both parties treated it as having been made on that date.
24. Clause 1(c) of the Agreement recorded that all transactions entered into in reliance on the Agreement formed a single transaction between the parties. This clause was not specific to the Agreement in issue in this appeal but was a general provision which would apply however many transactions two parties undertook under one agreement. It normally had relevance to the netting provisions (which provided that where amounts were payable by each party to the other the obligations were automatically discharged by the party by whom the larger amount was payable paying to the other the excess of the amount he owed over the amount owed by the other party). The netting provisions were not used in the transactions between the Appellant and International.
25. Clause 5 of the Agreement contained provisions which were applicable in events of default and termination. Events of default included failure to pay or deliver, and bankruptcy. Clause 6 provided that, where an event of default occurred, the non defaulting party could, by notice, designate an early termination date in respect of all outstanding transactions. When an early termination date occurred then the parties could elect a payment method and a payment measure. Under the payment method elected by the Appellant and International any amount owing to a defaulting party were to be deducted from the amounts owing to a non-defaulting party and the balance only was payable. The payment measure elected by the Appellant and International was the market quotation measure under which quotations would be obtained from four reference market makers of an amount which would have the effect of preserving the economic equivalent of payment or delivery; the quotation showing the highest and lowest values would be disregarded and the others averaged.
26. Clause 9 of the Agreement provided that the Agreement could not be transferred by either party without the prior written consent of the other party.
27. The Agreement incorporated the 1991 ISDA Definitions. Section 8.4 of those Definitions dealt with the exercise of options and provided for the delivery of a notice of exercise by the buyer to the seller; delivery could be orally or by telephone.
28. Also on 29 December 1994 the Appellant as buyer, and International as seller, signed two trade confirmations. One was for 330,181 European style call options expiring on 29 April 1996 where the underlying index was the FTSE 100 Index. The strike price was 3,000 and the payoff was capped at the FTSE 100 level of 3,500. The premium paid was £69,338.103.00 and the settlement amount was shown as the lesser of the number of options times 500 (the result expressed as pounds sterling) or the FTSE Index less 3,000 multiplied by the number of options (the result expressed as pounds sterling). Under this provision the amount that International would be liable to pay to the Appellant on 29 April 1996 would, depending on the movement of the FTSE 100 Index, be between £0 and £165,090,500.00.
29. The second trade confirmation was for 330,181 European style put options expiring on 29 April 1996 where the underlying index was the FTSE level 3000. The strike price was 3,500 and payoff was capped at FTSE level 3000. The option premium was £80,661,897.00 and the settlement amount was the lesser of 500 multiplied by the number of options (the result expressed as pounds sterling) or 3500 less the FTSE Index multiplied by the number of options (the result expressed as pounds sterling). Under this provision the amount that International would be liable to pay to the Appellant on 29 April 1996 would, depending on the movement of the FTSE 100 Index, be between £165,090,500.00 and £0.
30. Thus, the aggregate amount paid by the Appellant to International on 29 December 1994 was £150M (being the total of £69,338,103.00 and £80,661,897.00). The amounts paid for the purchase of the options represented the fair market value at the time the purchases were made when call options were cheaper than put options. Depending upon whether the FTSE 100 Index moved up or down, a greater or lesser amount would be paid on the exercise of the call option and the put option respectively. Taking the two arrangements together, however, the result would always be that International would, on 29 April 1996, be liable to pay to the Appellant the sum of £165,090,500.00.
31. Internally the Appellant dealt with the transactions as options and not loans.
The exercise of the options – 29 April 1996
32. There was no written evidence of the exercise of the options on 29 April 996. However, we accept the oral evidence of Mr Golden that it was market practice up to 1994 to accept exercise of options under the ISDA agreements orally or by telephone and that, after 1994, the primary method of exercise was by telephone. We note that section 5.2 of the 1994 ISDA Equity Option Definitions provides that oral telephonic notice is preferable to written notice. We also accept the unchallenged written evidence of Mr Schweitzer that it was not unusual to exercise options by way of telephone call or orally and that it was not unusual to assume exercise.
33. We therefore find that, on the balance of probabilities, the options were validly exercised on 29 April 1996.
As I have already mentioned the Crown concedes that each of the two options if taken separately would be a "qualifying option" within the meaning of s.128 of the 1988 Act as defined and that in order to succeed Mr McCall must persuade me that the proper legal analysis is to treat both options as part of a single composite transaction under which CIL has paid over the premiums amounting to £150m for a pre-determined fixed return of £165,090,500m payable in April 1996 without regard to the then state of the share market as recorded in the FTSE 100 Index. Such an agreement, says Mr McCall, would not be an option which "relates to shares" within the meaning of s.144(8)(c)(i) of the 1992 Act and cannot therefore be a qualifying option.
(i) do the two options constitute a single composite transaction for the purpose of applying the Ramsay principle;
(ii) if so, is that composite transaction one to which the Ramsay doctrine can apply having regard to the decision of the House of Lords in Furniss v Dawson; and
(iii) if it can so apply, does it have the effect of taking the two options, when regarded as a single composite transaction, outside the definition of a qualifying option within the meaning of s.128 of the 1988 Act.
Before turning to the specific questions posed in paragraph 9 above it is important to make one or two general observations about the origin and purpose of what for convenience I have called the Ramsay principle. Until the decision in Ramsay itself the leading authority as to how the courts should construe transactions in a fiscal context was the decision of the House of Lords in IRC v Duke of Westminster [1936] AC1. This decision has never been overruled and remains binding upon me.
"it is said that in revenue cases there is a doctrine that the Court may ignore the legal position and regard what is called "the substance of the matter," and that here the substance of the matter is that the annuitant was serving the Duke for something equal to his former salary or wages, and that therefore, while he is so serving, the annuity must be treated as salary or wages. This supposed doctrine (upon which the Commissioners apparently acted) seems to rest for its support upon a misunderstanding of language used in some earlier cases. The sooner this misunderstanding is dispelled, and the supposed doctrine given its quietus, the better it will be for all concerned, for the doctrine seems to involve substituting " the uncertain and crooked cord of discretion " for " the golden and straight metwand of the law." Every man is entitled if he can to order his affairs so as that the tax attaching under the appropriate Acts is less than it otherwise would be. If he succeeds in ordering them so as to secure this result, then, however unappreciative the Commissioners of Inland Revenue or his fellow taxpayers may be of his ingenuity, he cannot be compelled to pay an increased tax. This so-called doctrine of " the substance " seems to me to be nothing more than an attempt to make a man pay notwithstanding that he has so ordered his affairs that the amount of tax sought from him is not legally claimable.
The principal passages relied upon are from opinions of Lord Herschell and Lord Halsbury in your Lordships' House. Lord Herschell LC in Helby v Malthews observed: " It is said that the substance of the transaction evidenced by the agreement must be looked at, and not its mere words. I quite agree; " but he went on to explain that the substance must be ascertained by a consideration of the rights and obligations of the parties to be derived from a consideration of the whole of the agreement. In short Lord Herschell was saying that the substance of a transaction embodied in a written instrument is to be found by construing the document as a whole.
Support has also been sought by the appellants from the language of Lord Halsbury LC in Secretary of State in Council of India v Scoble. There Lord Halsbury said: " Still, looking at the whole nature and substance of the transaction (and it is agreed on all sides that we must look at the nature of the transaction and not be bound by the mere use of the words), this is not the case of a purchase of an annuity." Here again Lord Halsbury is only giving utterance to the indisputable rule that the surrounding circumstances must be regarded in construing a document.
Neither of these passages in my opinion affords the appellants any support or has any application to the present case. The matter was put accurately by my noble and learned friend Lord Warrington of Clyffe when as Warrington LJ in In re hinckes, Dashwood v Hinckes he used these words:
"It is said we must go behind the form and look at the substance… but, in order to ascertain the substance, I must look at the legal effect of the bargain which the parties have entered into." So here the substance is that which results from the legal rights and obligations of the parties ascertained upon ordinary legal principles, and, having ascertained upon ordinary legal principles, and, having regard to what I have already said, the conclusion must be that each annuitant is entitled to an annuity which as between himself and the payer is liable to deduction of income tax by the payer and which the payer is entitled to treat as a deduction from his total income for surtax purposes.
Coming then to the examination of the agreement, I quite concede that the agreement must be regarded as a whole - its substance must be looked at. The parties cannot, by the insertion of any mere words, defeat the effect of the transaction as appearing from the whole of the agreement into which they have entered. If the words in one part of it point in one direction and the words in another part in another direction, you must look at the agreement as a whole and see what its substantial effect is. But there is no such thing, as seems to have been argued here, as looking at the substance, apart from looking at the language which the parties have sued. It is only by a study of the whole of the language that the substance can be ascertained.
Similarly in Lloyds & Scottish Finance Ltd v Cyril Lord Carpet Sales Ltd reported in [1992] BCLC 609 but decided in 1979 Lord Wilberforce, in considering whether certain assignment of book debts were in substance absolute assignments by way of sale or assignments by way of charge would be void against a liquidator for non-registration under the Companies Act said this (at pp 614-5).
The total dependence of the assignment of the debts upon the trading agreement, the importance attached to the completion of the trading agreement before any money was advanced, show beyond doubt that the trading agreement was an essential element of the parties' contractual intention, and that the assignment were made under it. To suppose, in the fact of this, that the assignments were not by way of sale but by way of security, would be to impose upon the parties a form of transaction totally different from that which they had selected, namely one of sale and which there is no evidence whatever that either of them desired. Indeed there was evidence uncontradicted from the respondents witnesses and accepted by both courts below that the respondents 'had no intention of creating any charge over book debts or merely making a series of loans'. It would be a strange doctrine of 'looking for the substance' or 'looking through the documents' which would produce a contractual intention so clearly negated by the documents and by oral evidence.
But the principal argument of the Crown advanced in both appeals was that self-cancelling schemes, even if not shams in the sense described by Diplock LJ in Snook v West Riding Investments Ltd [1967] 2QB 786, should be looked at for the purpose of determining their fiscal consequences not on a step by step or transaction by transaction basis but rather as a single composite transaction whose ultimate legal effect should determine the tax treatment to be afforded to it. In the case of schemes of the kind under consideration in Ramsay the tax consequences would be neutral because the taxpayer had made neither a loss nor a gain. The chargeable gains accruing from the original transaction therefore remained taxable.
"…….it is the clear and stated intention that once started each scheme shall proceed through the various steps to the end – they are not intended to be arrested half-way. This intention may be expressed either as a firm contractual obligation (it is so in Rawling) or as in Ramsay as an expectation without contractual force."
In these circumstances, your Lordship are invited to take, with regard to schemes of the character I have described, what may appear to be a new approach. We are asked, in fact, to treat them as fiscally, a nullity not producing either a gain or a loss. Mr Potter QC described this as revolutionary, so I think it opportune to restate some familiar principles and some of the leading decisions so as to show the position we are now in.
1. A subject is only to be taxed upon clear words, not upon "intendment" or upon the "equity" of an Act. Any taxing Act of Parliament is to be construed in accordance with this principle. What are "clear words" is to be ascertained upon normal principles: these do not confine the courts to literal interpretation. There may, indeed should, be considered the context and scheme of the relevant Act as a whole, and its purpose may, indeed should, be regarded: see Inland Revenue Commissioners v Wesleyan and General Assurance Society (1946) 30 TC11, 16 per Lord Greene MR and Mangin v Inland Revenue Commissioner [19711 AC 739, 746, per Lord Donovan. The relevant Act in these cases is the Finance Act 1965, the purpose of which is to impose a tax on gains less allowable losses, arising from disposals.
2. A subject is entitled to arrange his affairs so as to reduce his liability to tax. The fact that the motive for a transaction may be to avoid tax does not invalidate it unless a particular enactment so provides. It must be considered according to its legal effect.
3. It is for the fact-finding commissioners to find whether a document, or a transaction, is genuine or a sham. In this context to say that a document or transaction is a "sham" means that while professing to be one thing, it is in fact something different. To say that a document or transaction is genuine, means that, in law, it is what it professes to be, and it does not mean anything more than that. I shall return to this point.
Each of these three principles would be fully respected by the decision we are invited to make. Something more must be said as to the next principle.
4. Given that a document or transaction is genuine, the court cannot go behind it to some supposed underlying substance. This is the well known principle of Inland Revenue Commissioners v Duke of Westminster [1936] AC1. This is a cardinal principle but it must not be overstated or overextended. While obliging the court to accept documents or transactions, found to be genuine, as such, it does not compel the court to look at a document or a transaction in blinkers, isolated from any context to which it properly belongs. If it can be seen that a document or transaction was intended to have effect as part of a nexus or series of transactions, or as an ingredient of a wider transaction intended as a whole, there is nothing in the doctrine to prevent it being so regarded: to do so is not to prefer from to substance, or substance to form. It is the task of the court to ascertain the legal nature of any transaction to which it is sought to attach a tax or a tax consequence and if that emerges from a series or combination of transactions, intended to operate as such, it is that series or combination which may be regarded. For this there is authority in the law relating to income tax and capital gains tax: see Chinn v Hochstrasser [19811 AC 533 and Inland Revenue Commissioners v Plummer [19801 AC 896.
For the commissioners considering a particular case it is wrong, and an unnecessary self limitation, to regard themselves as precluded by their own finding that documents or transactions are not "shams", from considering what, as evidenced by the documents themselves or by the manifested intentions of the parties, the relevant transaction is. They are not, under the Westminster doctrine or any other authority, bound to consider individually each separate step in a composite transaction intended to be carried through as a whole. This is particularly the case where (as in Rawling) it is proved that there was an accepted obligation once a scheme is set in motion, to carry it through its successive steps. It may not be so where (as in Ramsay or in Black Nominees Ltd v Nicol (1975) 50 TC 229) there is an expectation that it will be so carried through, and no likelihood in practice that it will not. In such cases (which may vary in emphasis) the commissioners should find the facts and then decide as a matter (reviewable) of law whether what is in issue is a composite transaction, or a number of independent transactions.
In dealing with Income Tax questions it frequently happens that there are two methods at least of achieving a particular financial result. If one of those methods is adopted, tax will be payable. If the other method is adopted, tax will not be payable. It is sufficient to refer to the quite common case where property is sold for a lump sum payable by instalments. If a piece of property is sold for £1,000 and the purchase price is to be paid in ten instalments of £100 each, no tax is payable. If, on the other hand, the property is sold in consideration of an annuity of £100 a year for ten years, tax is payable. The net result from the financial point of view is precisely the same in each case, but one method of achieving it attracts tax and the other method does not.
There have been cases in the past, where what has been called the substance of the transaction has been thought to enable the Court to construe a document in such a way as to attract tax. That particular doctrine of substance as distinct from form was, I hope, finally exploded by the decision of the House of Lords in the case of The Duke of Westminster v Commissioners of Inland Revenue, 19 TC 490.
The effect of a contract cannot be judged by isolating one clause and ignoring the remainder. A circular contract which requires one asset to be revolved in a circle must be judged by the difference, if any, between the position of each party at the start and at the finish of the contract. Two or more independent contracts may produce a circle and the effect of each contract must be judged according to its terms without regard to any other contract. But one single circular contract, or a series of interdependent contracts, which revolves one property in a circle cannot be divided into separate transactions in order to determine the effect of the contract or series.
In the present case the one property which was dealt with consisted of the debt of £600,000. The contract provided that the taxpayer would only acquire an interest in the debt of £600,000 subject to a duty and right for that interest to be passed on without gain or loss to himself. So far as the taxpayer is concerned, he began with nothing, by contract he gained nothing and lost nothing and he ended with nothing. The effect of the contract was that he paid £9,985 for an argument which proves to be worth nothing.
Lord Wilberforce directs the commissioners to look for "the relevant transaction". But the "relevant transaction" may be one which essentially involves the constituent steps. To put shares into a company so that they and any subsequent proceeds of their sale are held by the company necessarily involves in itself a disposal in fact which, after all, means no more than the divesting of the asset from the original holder. Once he has divested himself he has "disposed" although the statute tells us that he is to be treated as not having done so, and the question is whether, on that disposal, a gain accrues. If the transaction, whatever it is, involves factually two dispositions, I cannot see in this part of Lord Wilberforce's speech anything which compels the commissioners to find that it is one disposition. It remains two dispositions though no doubt connected dispositions and the question is what is the legal effect of those dispositions taken together. For myself, I entirely fail to see why a combination of transactions has necessarily to be labelled as "sale of shares by A to C" rather than "vesting of shares by A in the B Co. and the sale of the shares by the B Co. to C. " It happens that the combination of transactions does not involve the payment of capital gains tax unless and until A sells his shares in the B Co., but if that is the combination of transactions which the parties intended to carry out, then I am unable to follow why there should be attributed to them, for the fiscal purposes and only for fiscal purposes, some quite different transaction which they did not intend merely because the end result is, so far as C is concerned, but not A, the same
"It would be disingenuous to suggest, and dangerous on the part of those who advise on elaborate tax-avoidance schemes to assume, that Ramsay's case did not mark a significant change in the approach adopted by this House in its judicial role to a preordained series of transaction (whether or not they include the achievement of a legitimate commercial end) into which there are inserted steps that have no commercial purpose apart from the avoidance of a liability to tax which in the absence of those particular steps would have been payable. The difference is in approach. It does not necessitate the overruling of any earlier decisions of this House; but it does involve recognising that Lord Tomlin's oft-quoted dictum in Inland Revenue Commissioners v Duke of Westminster [1931 AC1, 19, 'Every man is entitled if he can to order his affairs so as that the tax attaching under the appropriate Acts is less than it otherwise would be, tells us little or nothing as to what methods of ordering one's affairs will be recognised by the courts as effective to lessen the tax that would attach to them if business transactions were conducted in a straightforward way."
The formulation by Lord Diplock in Inland Revenue Commissioners v Burmah Oil Co Ltd [1982] STC 30, 33 expresses the limitations of the Ramsay principle. First, there must be a preordained series of transactions; or, if one likes, one single composite transaction. This composite transaction may or may not include the achievement of a legitimate commercial (i.e. business) end. The composite transaction does, in the instant case; it achieved a sale of the shares in the operating companies by the Dawsons to Wood Bastow. It did not in Ramsay. Secondly, there must be steps inserted which have no commercial (business) purpose apart from the avoidance of a liability to tax-not "no business effect." If those two ingredients exist, the inserted steps are to be disregarded for fiscal purposes. The court must then look at the end result. Precisely how the end result will be taxed will depend on the terms of the taxing stature sought to be applied.
In the instant case the inserted step was the introduction of Greenjacket as a buyer from the Dawsons and as a seller to Wood Bastow. That inserted step had no business purpose apart from the deferment of tax, although it had a business effect. If the sale had taken place in 1964 before capital gains tax was introduced, there would have been no Greenjacket.
The formulation, therefore, involves two findings of fact, first, whether there was a preordained series of transactions, i.e. a single composite transaction, secondly, whether that transaction contained steps which were inserted without any commercial or business purpose apart from a tax advantage. Those are facts to be found by the commissioners. They may be primary facts or, more probably, inferences to be drawn from the primary facts. If they are inferences, they are nevertheless facts to be found by the commissioners. Such inferences of fact cannot be disturbed by the court save on Edwards v Bairstow [1956] AC 14 principles.
The first essential finding of fact if the Crown is to succeed on this appeal is that the two options were a single composite transaction. In Furniss v Dawson (at p.527) Lord Brightman treats this as synonymous with a "preordained series of transactions" and if CIL is right in its argument that there must be inserted steps before Ramsay can operate then that will be an accurate description of any composite transaction to which the doctrine can apply. For the moment however I shall confine myself to what needs to be proved in order to make a finding that two or more transactions should be treated as composite for these purposes.
As the law currently stands, the essential emerging from Furniss v Dawson [1984]AC 474 appear to me to be four in number: (1) that the series of transactions was, at the time when the intermediate transaction was entered into, pre-ordained in order to produce a given result; (2) that the transaction had no other purpose than tax mitigation; (3) that there was at that time no practical likelihood that the pre-planned events would not take place in the order ordained, so that the intermediate transaction was not even contemplated practically as having an independent life, and (4) that the pre-ordained events did in fact take place. In these circumstances the court can be justified in linking the beginning with the end so as to make a single composite whole to which the fiscal results of the single composite whole are to be applied.
I do not for my part think that Furniss v Dawson goes further than that the intellectual basis for the decision was Ramsay and the criteria for the application of the Ramsay doctrine were those enunciated by Lord Brightman.
Mr McCall accepts that the equity box scheme does not involve the insertion of steps with no commercial purpose other than the avoidance of a liability to tax. Therefore if the test in Furniss v Dawson requires to be satisfied the appeal must fail. Despite Mr McCall's eloquent attempts to persuade me otherwise I remain of the view that the test laid down by Lord Brightman is exhaustive and that the requirement he set out are a necessary pre-condition for the application of the Ramsay principle. For the same reason I am not satisfied that there remains some underlying or residual principle which can apply to transactions of the kind in question which have a clear commercial purpose, contain no artificial steps and were entered into for full market value on recognised terms.
Now it has, I think, to be accepted that Furniss v Dawson, whilst it purported to do no more than apply the Ramsay principle to a different set of facts, involved in fact an extension of the principle and it did so not simply because it applied the principle to a "linear" transaction as opposed to a circular transaction. The Ramsay principle is simply that you look at the result which the parties actually intended to and did produce and apply to it the ordinary fiscal consequences which flow from that result. Furniss involved going a considerable step further than this and, by reconstituting the actual constituent transactions into something that they were not in fact, attributing to the parties an intended result which they did not in fact intend. To that unintended result there are then attached the fiscal consequences which would have flowed if the transaction had actually taken form into which it is deemed to be reconstituted. It has to be borne in mind that the particular transaction with which Furniss was concerned, and with which each of the three appeals before your Lordships is concerned, was one in which an actual exchange of shares had taken place, a transaction which had permanent legal and fiscal results and to which certain fiscal provisions applied from the moment at which the transaction was effected. The critical question is that of identifying the circumstances in which such a transactions can be simply ignored and in which so radical a reconstruction of the actual events as that undertaken in Furniss v Dawson is permissible and is to be undertaken by the court and whether, apart from the concept of tripartite contract upon which reliance was placed in reaching the decision in Furniss, such a reconstitution is rationally and logically possible within the accepted principles of construction provided by Ramsay or, indeed, any other principle.
The point is taken up again at page 513F where he said this:
How, in the absence of contractual obligation, is the revenue's sought for result to be obtained? The answer is to be arrived at in two stages. First of all through Ramsay, because that establishes that where there is (i) a scheme involving a series of transactions plus (ii) an expectation that it will be carried through from beginning to end and (iii) no likelihood that it will not, the court is not bound, in assessing the fiscal consequences to consider each step individually and accord to it its individual legal result but is entitled to look at the composite transaction as a single transaction having a single legal result. This dispenses with the need for a contractual obligation but to achieve that result all three of the enumerated elements must be present. They were present in Furniss v Dawson and, there being in the exercise no necessity for contractual obligation linking the beginning with the end but merely a confident expectation, the court was able to look at the overall transaction and to assess its legal result as a composite whole. But it was able to do this because it was in fact not only conceived but carried out as one indivisible transaction. However, that in itself was not enough, because if you merely did that you still ended up with the statutory fiscal results of an actual disposition by the Dawsons via Greenjacket to Wood Bastow and the price firmly locked in Greenjacket. You have to go one stage further to nullify the intermediate transfer to Greenjacket which has its own permanent fiscal consequences unless it can be totally disregarded, for Ramsay merely "enables the courts to arrive at a conclusion which corresponds with the parties' intentions". In Furniss v Dawson the parties' intention was to produce a sale by Greenjacket instead of a sale by the Dawsons. So a further ingredient has to be supplied, and that is found in Burman. This establishes the further proposition that if you find in what, ex-hypothesis, is an integrated and interdependent series of transactions a step inserted which has no other purpose that that of avoiding or minimising a liability to tax which, without that step, would be attracted by the transactions, you are entitled for fiscal purposes to ignore that step in assessing what is the true legal result of the series taken as a whole. So, in reliance upon these two authorities, the House set about considering the true legal effect of the transactions undertaken and they were able to arrive at the conclusion, that although there was in fact no contractual connection between the steps making the tripartite contract, the circumstances were such that the steps could be treated together in exactly the same way as if there were.
In the light of my judgment on the first two issues it is not strictly necessary for me to reach any decision on Mr Aaronson's alternative argument that the two options, even if part of a composite transaction, would still constitute a qualifying option if analysed in accordance with Mr McCall's under-lying Ramsay principle. But this third issue is in fact resolved by my determination of the previous two issues.
For all these reasons the appeal will be dismissed.