BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales High Court (Chancery Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales High Court (Chancery Division) Decisions >> Polo Woods Foundation v Shelton-Agar & Anor [2009] EWHC 1361 (Ch) (17 June 2009) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWHC/Ch/2009/1361.html Cite as: [2009] 2 P & CR DG20, [2010] 1 All ER 539, [2009] EWHC 1361 (Ch), [2010] 1 P & CR 12 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
CHANCERY DIVISION
ON APPEAL FROM THE ADJUDICATOR TO
HER MAJESTY'S LAND REGISTRY
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
____________________
POLO WOODS FOUNDATION |
Appellant |
|
- and - |
||
MICHAEL ALAN SHELTON-AGAR (1) SARAH KATHERINE SHELTON-AGAR (2) |
Respondents |
____________________
William Batstone (instructed by Messrs Penningtons LLP) for the Respondents
Hearing date: 5th February 2009
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
Mr Justice Warren :
The Decision
"As I have stated I am satisfied that for over 20 years from 1972 onwards an indefinite number of ponies (never more than 10 and frequently less than 5) entered onto the Triangle between the hours of 5.30 pm to 6.00 between March and October as part of their daily routine and that, in the course of so doing, they occasionally grazed. Taken on its own, the Triangle would not be capable of providing enough stocking material for even one horse over the period in question."
"It is not, on any footing, necessary for the Farm to be able to allow ponies to graze on this land [the Triangle]. The value of the grass on the Triangle is negligible. As I have said above, the grass can only provide grazing for less than one horse over the period".
Ms McAllister's analysis and conclusions
"76. Mr Cowen argues that the test is not whether the right sought is necessary, but whether it is reasonably necessary, and that this is to be tested subjectively. I agree (subject to the points made below) that the test is not one of strict necessity, and also agree with the further point that the test is whether the right benefits the dominant tenement rather than the owner at any given time of the tenement. This is why the question is not (or is not necessarily) whether the right confers a commercial benefit. But I disagree that the test is a subjective one. It is a question of fact in each case, dependent on the nature of the dominant tenement and the right claimed. The connection must be a real one. Even if the test were subjective, I heard no evidence to suggest that any one involved in the Farm seriously believed that the Triangle could provide any real or appreciable benefit to the Farm. On the contrary, it seemed to me quite clear to everyone that there would be no additional benefit in being able to use the Triangle for grazing.77. The formulation in earlier authorities (such as Lord Chesterfield v Harris) that there must be some relation between the needs of the estate and the extent of the profits, or that the right is limited to the wants of the estate is, in my judgment, another way of articulating the test (whilst also taking account of the particular nature of common rights). It is an important test. It is not enough to say that it is merely an 'accident of title' (as Mr Cowen put it) which means that the Triangle is in separate ownership. Without an objective test relating the profit sought to the needs of the estate, one or two horses, occasionally grazing on any land, however small, and regardless of the extent of the dominant tenement or the real benefit to the dominant land, could create a profit in favour of the dominant tenement. On the facts of this case the benefit to the dominant land is, it seems to me, so slight as to fail this test."
a. The rules and principles governing the acquisition of profits are the same as those for easements.
b. The right claimed must accommodate the dominant land and be capable of being the subject matter of a grant.
c. The test is an objective one and must relate the right sought to the needs of the estate. The test is whether there is a real benefit to the estate.
d. On the fact of this case, the benefit to the dominant land is so slight as to fail this test.
Mr Cowen accepts the first two of those propositions (indeed, they are common ground) but not the third and fourth.
a. The maximum number of ponies which made use of the Triangle could not be identified.
b. The right claimed is too wide and vague in character.
c. The right claimed would substantially deprive the owners of the Triangle of possession (the "ouster" argument).
d. The right claimed possesses no quality of utility or benefit.
e. The user relied upon lacks the requisite quality of being as of right.
f. The right claimed cannot be acquired by prescription because it is incapable of judicial control.
The nature of a profit ? prendre and the relevant law
Nature and extent
"A profit ? prendre is a right to take something off another person's land. It may be more fully defined as a right to enter another's land to take some profit of the soil, or a portion of the soil itself, for the use of the owner of the right."
"whether it is correct to imply that a profit of pasture appurtenant can never in any circumstances be acquired by prescription for a fixed number of animals, but that does not affect the basic point that prescription of a profit appurtenant must be by way of activities which accommodate the land to which it becomes appurtenant".
Acquisition
"To make good a prescriptive claim in this case it is not necessary for the claimant to establish that he and his predecessors have exercised the right claimed continuously. This is a profit of a kind that, of its nature, would only be used intermittently. Flocks would not, for instance, be on the down at lambing time, or for 24 hours of the day, or very possibly on every day of the week or all round the year. But the user must be shown to have been of such a character, degree and frequency as to indicate an assertion by the claimant of a continuous right, and of a right of the measure of the right claimed." [my emphasis]
Characteristics of a valid profit ? prendre
a. There must be a dominant and servient tenement.
b. The easement or profit must accommodate the dominant tenement.
c. The dominant and servient tenements must not both be owned or occupied by the same person.
d. The easement or profit must be capable of forming the subject matter of a grant.
"……it was one of the main submissions by Mr. Cross on behalf of the appellant that the right of full enjoyment of the park, granted to the purchaser by the conveyance of December 23, 1864, was insufficiently connected with the enjoyment of the property conveyed, in that it did not subserve some use which was to be made of that property; and that such a right accordingly could not exist in law as an easement. In this part of his argument Mr. Cross was invoking a principle which is, in our judgment, of unchallengeable authority, expounded, in somewhat varying language, in many judicial utterances, of which the judgments in Ackroyd v. Smith (1850) 10 CB 164 are, perhaps, most commonly cited. We think it unnecessary to review the authorities in which the principle has been applied; for the effect of the decisions is stated with accuracy in Dr. Cheshire's Modern Real Property, 7th ed., at p. 457. After pointing out that "one of the fundamental principles concerning easements is that they must be not only appurtenant to a dominant tenement, but also connected with the normal enjoyment of the dominant tenement" and referring to certain citations in support of that proposition the author proceeded: "We may expand the statement of the principle thus: a right enjoyed by one over the land of another does not possess the status of an easement unless it accommodates and serves the dominant tenement, and is reasonably necessary for the better enjoyment of that tenement, for if it has no necessary connexion therewith, although it confers an advantage upon the owner and renders his ownership of the land more valuable, it is not an easement at all, but a mere contractual right personal to and only enforceable between the two contracting parties."
"been stated in many ways: -
"An easement must be connected with the enjoyment of the dominant tenement and must be for its benefit." [Fn Gale on Easement (12th ed)]
"It must have some natural connection with the estate as being for its benefit." [Fn Bailey v Stephens (1862) 12 CBNS 91]
"The incident sought to be annexed…..must be beneficial to the land in respect of the ownership". [Fn ibid (although this reference seems to be incorrect)]
"perhaps best illustrated by Hill v Tupper, where the facts were as follows:A canal company leased land adjoining the canal to Hill and gave him the "sole and exclusive right" to let out pleasure boats on the canal. Tupper, an innkeeper, disregarded this privilege by himself letting out boats for fishing purposes. Hill thereupon brought an action in his own name against Tupper, his alleged cause of action being a disturbance of his easement to put boats on the canal.It was held that the right conferrned upon Hill by the contract with the company was not an easement but a mere licence personal to himself, since it obviously did not exist for the accommodation and better enjoyment of the land held by him at the waterside. The right was not beneficial to the land as land; rather, the land was required for the exploitation of the right."
"Can it be said, then, of the right of full enjoyment of the park in question…..that it accommodated and served that property? It is clear that the right did, in some degree, enhance the value of the property, and this consideration cannot be dismissed as wholly irrelevant. It is, of course, a point to be noted; but we agree with Mr. Cross's submission that it is in no way decisive of the problem; it is not sufficient to show that the right increased the value of the property conveyed, unless it is also shown that it was connected with the normal enjoyment of that property. It appears to us that the question whether or not this connexion exists is primarily one of fact, and depends largely on the nature of the alleged dominant tenement and the nature of the right granted….. ……..Mr. Cross submitted that the requisite connexion between the right to use the park and the normal enjoyment of the houses which were built around it or near it had not been established. He likened the position to a right granted to the purchaser of a house to use the Zoological Gardens free of charge or to attend Lord's Cricket Ground without payment. Such a right would undoubtedly, he said, increase the value of the property conveyed but could not run with it at law as an easement, because there was no sufficient nexus between the enjoyment of the right and the use of the house."
After rejecting that analogy, Evershed MR went on:
"A much closer analogy, as it seems to us, is the case of a man selling the freehold of part of his house and granting to the purchaser, his heirs and assigns, the right, appurtenant to such part, to use the garden in common with the vendor and his assigns. In such a case, the test of connexion, or accommodation, would be amply satisfied; for just as the use of a garden undoubtedly enhances, and is connected with, the normal enjoyment of the house to which it belongs, so also would the right granted, in the case supposed, be closely connected with the use and enjoyment of the part of the premises sold.……….The test for present purposes, no doubt, is that the park should constitute in a real and intelligible sense the garden (albeit the communal garden) of the houses to which its enjoyment is annexed……".
"… there be a natural connection between the dominant and servient tenement. The right must be reasonably necessary for the enjoyment of the dominant tenement and not merely confer an advantage on the owner of that tenement, as would a mere contractual right."
Needs of the estate
a. Profits of turbary. This is the right to dig and take peat or turf for use as fuel in a house. It can be used only for use in the house and cannot be taken for sale even if the owner is entitled to a fixed quantity.
b. Profits of estovers. This is the right to take wood from the land of another for certain purposes. Similar considerations apply.
c. Profit of pasture. This is the right to take away pasture, the taking away being effected by means of the mouths and stomachs of the cattle. As with any other profit, there must be a limit on the amount which can be taken. Unless limited to a definite number of cattle, the amount is limited by the needs of the estate which, in this context, is the number of cattle levant and couchant which can be supported by the dominant tenement.
a. that a profit appurtenant may not be unlimited; and
b. that the limit must be related to the needs of the estate.
The decisions and reasoning of Ms McAllister
a. In paragraph 75: Only 70% of the Triangle can be grazed and the value of the grass is negligible – the grass could only provide grazing for less than one horse over the period sought.
b. In paragraph 76: There was "no evidence to suggest that anyone involved in the Farm seriously believed that the Triangle could provide any real or appreciable benefit to the Farm. On the contrary, it seemed to me quite clear that there would be no additional benefit in being able to use the Triangle for grazing".
c. In paragraph 77: "the benefit to the dominant land is, it seems to me, so slight as to fail this test".
a. The use of the Common and other fields at night is standard practice to stop animals eating too much and developing certain disorders;
b. It is highly unlikely that the ponies would have been intensively feeding but rather the fields were used as a loafing or exercising area;
c. Loafing, however, includes some element of feeding and;
d. The optimum number of ponies on the Triangle would be 5.
a. The first reason is, he says, to be found in paragraphs 75 and 76 where she expresses her conclusion. She had identified in paragraph 23 of the Decision that two elements were required namely (a) some geographical connection and (b) in a real and intelligible sense a benefit to the dominant tenement. The words "real and intelligible sense" come, as I have said, from Re Ellenborough Park and do not, for reasons given, justify a "real or appreciable benefit" test which are the words used by Ms McAllister in paragraph 76. Similarly, those words as used by Santow JA do not justify such a test.
b. The second relates to the need for a relation between the needs of the estate and the extent of the profit. There was, he says, no evidence of any relationship between the needs of the Farm and the right claimed, going on to assert that it is "reasonable to infer from this part of the decision that the Adjudicator was expressing herself to be not satisfied of this condition of the establishment of a profit ? prendre".
"one or two horses, occasionally grazing on any land, however small and regardless of the extent of the dominant tenement or the real benefit to the dominant land, could create a profit in favour of the dominant tenement."
Maximum number of ponies
"The numbers of ponies at any given time on the Triangle fluctuated from 3 to 10. The purpose of putting them out onto the Common, and the purpose of going onto the Triangle, was both to graze and to loaf or exercise."
"It also seems to me that the fact that the number may have fluctuated over time is irrelevant: what matters is that a maximum number of ponies can be identified. The right, by definition, is only enjoyed intermittently (see White v Taylor (N0 2)."
If she is to be read as saying that, because the evidence establishes grazing by a maximum of 10 ponies ("never more than 10 and frequently less than 5"), a right for 10 ponies to graze is established, then I must respectfully disagree, especially in the context where 3 is the largest regular number established by her findings. I do not, however, think that that is what she was saying. She was addressing, I believe, the point that a fluctuating number would, of necessity, render the right claimed uncertain, a proposition rightly rejected. What she did not do was make a finding, on the evidence before her, about the maximum number of ponies in respect of which the right to graze was established. All she did was to determine the maximum number of ponies which had occasionally been on the Triangle.
The right claimed is too wide and vague in character.
Ouster
The right claimed possesses no quality of utility or benefit.
The user relied upon lacks the requisite quality of being as of right.
The right claimed cannot be acquired by prescription because it is incapable of judicial control.
Conclusions