BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales High Court (Chancery Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales High Court (Chancery Division) Decisions >> Seafood Holdings Ltd v My Fish Company Ltd & Ors [2017] EWHC 766 (Ch) (07 April 2017) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWHC/Ch/2017/766.html Cite as: [2017] EWHC 766 (Ch) |
[New search] [Printable PDF version] [Help]
CHANCERY DIVISION
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
____________________
Seafood Holdings Limited |
Claimant |
|
- and - |
||
(1)My Fish Company Limited (2) Gary Apps (3) Benjamin Philip Coupe (4) Mark Ormiston (5) Mark Hadland |
Defendants |
____________________
Martin Budworth and Douglas Cochran (instructed by JMW LLP) for the Defendants
Hearing date: 2 December 2016
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
Mr Justice Norris :
"I would add, with regard in particular to competition law claims (or defences), that where the area of law is in the course of development the court should be cautious "to assume that it is beyond argument with real prospect of success that the existing case law will not be extended or modified" so as to encompass the basis of argument advanced… Moreover, it is important that competition claims are pleaded properly. To contend that a party has infringed competition law involves a serious allegation of breach of a quasi-public law, which can lead to the imposition of financial penalties as well as civil liability. A defendant faced with such a claim is entitled to know what specific conduct or agreement is complained of and how that is alleged to violate the law. As Laddie J observed in BHB Enterprises v Victor Chandler International Ltd [2005] EWHC 1074 (Ch) at [43] "These are notoriously burdensome allegations, frequently leading to extensive evidence, including expert reports from economists and accountants. The recent history of cases in which such allegations have been raised illustrates that they can lead to lengthy and expensive trials." Subsequent experience only reinforces the accuracy of that observation. This is not to adopt an over technical approach to pleadings. It is consistent with the overriding objective to enable the case to be dealt with expeditiously and fairly. It is only through the clear articulation of each party's position in its statement of case, with appropriate factual detail, that the other side can know what case it has to meet and what issues any experts have to address, and that the court can effectively exercise its case management powers."
(a) the market identified by My Fish is the market in which both it and Seafood sell ("the downstream market");
(b) the allegation is that Seafood occupies a dominant position in that downstream market;
(c) that dominant position is said to derive from its 21-25% share of the market and from the fact that it has only one main rival (M&J Seafoods) which itself has only an 18% share of the defined market;
(d) the activities of which My Fish complains is in the market in which both it and Seafood buy ("the upstream market");
(e) there is no allegation that Seafood occupies a dominant position in that upstream market;
(f) according to the unchallenged evidence adduced by Seafood its purchasing activities account for about 2% of the upstream market.
(a) to identify the market;
(b) to establish the defendant's dominant position in the UK;
(c) to prove relevant conduct;
(d) to establish that it may affect trade within the UK.
"a position of economic strength …. which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by affording it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, its customers and ultimately of its consumers there… a position [which] does not preclude some competition... but enables the undertaking which profits by it, if not to determine, at least to have an appreciable influence on the conditions under which that competition will develop , and in any case to act largely in disregard of it so long as such conduct does not operate to its detriment."
That is a citation from Hoffman La Roche [1979] ECR 461 at [38] and [39].
"The Commission considers that low market shares are generally a good proxy for the absence of substantial market power. The Commission's experience suggests that dominance is not likely if the undertaking's market share is below 40% in the relevant market. However, there may be specific cases below that threshold where competitors are not in a position to constrain effectively the conduct of a dominant undertaking, for example where they face serious capacity limitations… "
"The OFT considers it unlikely that an undertaking will be individually dominant in its share of the relevant market is below 40%, although dominance could be established below that figure in other relevant factors such as the weak position of competitors in that market and high entry barriers provided strong evidence of dominance."
"Conduct may, in particular, constitute such an abuse if it consists in (a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions; (b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of consumers; (c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage; (d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of the contracts. "
"Given its almost complete domination of the aseptic markets, Tetra Pak could also count upon a favoured status of the non- aseptic markets. Thanks to its position on the former markets, it could concentrate its efforts on the latter by acting independently of the other economic operators. "
But there are plainly no such associative links relevant in the present case and none is pleaded.
"…Hilti's commercial behaviour …..is witness to its ability to act independently of, and without due regard to, either competitors or customers on the relevant markets in question… This behaviour and its economic consequences would not normally be seen where a company was facing real competitive pressure…. The freedom of action which had exercised in these markets with a disregard for other competitors and even customers such as distributors, is evidence of this dominance. By its behaviour and power derived from its position in the cartridge strip market Hilti has been able to severely limit any effective competition from independent producers of guilty compatible nails…"
A reading of the report demonstrates that the Hilti's conduct of which complaint (and which provide the context for the sentences relied on) was made was far removed anything alleged in this case.
"the benefit of the block exemption established by this Regulation should be limited to vertical agreements which it can be assumed with sufficient certainty that they satisfy the conditions of article 101(3) of the Treaty"
and it provides for a block exemption.
"It can be presumed that, where the market share held by each of the undertakings party to the agreement on the relevant market does not exceed 30%, vertical agreements which do not contain certain types of severe restrictions of competition generally lead to an improvement in production or distribution, and allow consumers a fair share of the resulting benefits."
"The exemption provided for in Article 2 shall apply on condition that the market share held by the supplier does not exceed 30% of the relevant market on which it sells the contract goods or services on the market share held by the buyer does not exceed 30% of the relevant market on which purchases the contract goods or services. "
"The market share of the buyer on the upstream purchase market is obviously important for assessing the ability of the buyer to impose exclusive supply which forecloses other buyers from access to supplies. The importance of the buyer on the downstream market is however the factor which determines whether a competition problem may arise. If the buyer has no market power downstream, then no appreciable negative effects for consumers can be expected. Negative effects may arise where the market share of the buyer on the downstream supply market as well as the upstream purchase market exceeds 30%. Where the market share of the buyer on the upstream market does not exceed 30%, significant foreclosure effects may still result, especially where the market share of the buyer on his downstream market exceeds 30% and the exclusive supply relates to a particular use of the contract products."