BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £5, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
Scottish Court of Session Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> Scottish Court of Session Decisions >> Baird & Brown v. Selkirk (Hugh Stirrat's Trustee) [1872] ScotLR 9_250_1 (26 January 1872) URL: http://www.bailii.org/scot/cases/ScotCS/1872/09SLR0250_1.html Cite as: [1872] ScotLR 9_250_1, [1872] SLR 9_250_1 |
[New search] [Printable PDF version] [Help]
Page: 250↓
Held ( dubit Lord Deas) that the proper order of ranking a body of creditors on the proceeds of the heritable estate of a bankrupt, where one of the creditors had used inhibition on his debt three months before the sequestration,—the debts of some of the creditors having been contracted before, and of others after the inhibition,—was, first, to rank all the creditors pari passu, and then to give the inhibiting creditor the difference between the dividend arising thereby, and what he would have drawn had no debts been contracted subsequent to the use of the inhibition, by way of drawback from the dividends of the creditors whose debts were contracted after the inhibition.
Subject_Bankruptcy Act 1856, sec. 127.
The trustee in a sequestration issued a deliverance, in which he explained the scheme of ranking, and addressed a copy to each creditor, stating the class in which he had placed his claim. Held that an appeal by a creditor against the deliverance on his own claim competently brought under review the whole scheme of ranking, and that it was not necessary for him to appeal against the deliverance on any other claim.
This was an appeal under section 170 of the Bankruptcy Act 1856, against an interlocutor of the Sheriff of Lanarkshire, affirming a deliverance of the trustee in the sequestration of the estates of Hugh Stirrat & Son, wrights and tun builders, Glasgow; and of Hugh Stirrat, the sole partner of the said firm, which were sequestrated on the 22d May 1871.
On the 22d February 1871 Robert Melville & Co. used inhibition on a debt due to them by the bankrupt. The debts due to the other creditors were not secured by inhibition. Some were contracted before, and others after the inhibition. Part of the bankrupt estate consisted of heritable properties, which were realised by the trustee.
On the 4th September 1871 the trustee issued and addressed to each creditor a deliverance, in which he explained the scheme of ranking which he adopted—“With reference to the rankings, I have to explain that an inhibition was used against the bankrupts on 22d February last, the effect of which is to separate the creditors into two classes: those whose claims existed at the date mentioned
Page: 251↓
being placed under class A in the state of interests, and being entitled, first, to rank on the heritable estate, and secondly, on the general estate, along with the other creditors, for any deficiency until they are paid in full; the whole creditors ranking on the general estate being placed under class B; and creditors not receiving dividend from heritable estate may receive a second ranking until also paid in full, if subsequent recoveries shall admit of this. To prevent misapprehension, I desire further to explain that the secondary ranking which the law gives to class A on the general estate, for the dividend of 11s. per £, is not equal to payment in full, as at first sight might appear—because their ranking is for the deficiency only, and not for the full debt;—the deduction of the primary ranking being equivalent to the valuation and deduction of their quasi-security under the inhibition.
The proposed dividends on claims admitted are these:—ten shillings per pound to creditors in class A; and eleven shillings per pound to creditors in class B; but in the event of my deliverances on claims being appealed, the dividends will fall to be altered according to the results of such appeals.”
To Messrs Baird & Brown the trustee intimated that their claim for £165, 17s. 4d. was sustained, and placed in class B, the debt having been contracted subsequent to the date of the inhibition. Similar notices were sent to the other creditors.
Baird & Brown appealed against this deliverance, “in so far as the trustee has divided the creditors into two classes—A and B—and in so far as he has ranked and preferred class A on the heritable estate, and has ranked the appellants under class B,” and they prayed the Sheriff “to recal the deliverance, and ordain the trustee to rank the appellants equally with the whole creditors not preferably secured upon the funds of the sequestrated estates.”
Minutes having been ordered by the Sheriff, the trustee, besides maintaining the soundness of the scheme of division, pleaded that, as the appellants had failed to appeal against the deliverance on the claims admitted under class A, they had now become final (Bankruptcy Act 1856, sec. 127), and that the attempt of the appellants to bring under review the whole scheme of division merely by an appeal against the deliverance on their own claim was incompetent.
The Sheriff pronounced the following interlocutor:—
“ Glasgow, 24 th November 1871.—Having again heard parties' procurators and reviewed the process, finds that it is settled—1st, That an inhibitor cannot be prejudiced by posterior debts; 2d, That anterior creditors, adjudgers within year and day of the inhibitor, cannot be prejudiced by the inhibition, and are entitled to be ranked pari passu with the inhibitor (Bell's Com., 7th ed., vol. ii, pp. 409 et seq.); finds that it is enacted, inter alia, by section 102 of the Bankruptcy (Scotland) Act, 1856, ‘that the act and warrant in favour of a trustee in a sequestration has the effect of vesting in him, as at the date of the sequestration, ‘for behoof of the creditors,’ the bankrupt's whole heritable estate, as if a decree of adjudication had been pronounced in his favour; finds that the vesting as above in the respondent's person occurred within year and day of the inhibition used by one of the creditors, and the effect of such vesting was to put all the anterior creditors on a par with the inhibitor; finds that it is the duty of the trustee to rank all the creditors according to their several rights and interests ( Id. sec. 121); finds that the scheme of ranking adopted in the present instance is equitable, and in conformity with the above principles; finds farther, and separatim, that to sustain this appeal would be tantamount to recalling all the deliverances which have been pronounced by the respondent on the claims of the anterior creditors, and that as no appeal has been taken by the appellant, as he might have done, against all or any of these deliverances, they are consequently final, and cannot now be cut down either directly or indirectly; therefore adheres to the deliverance appealed against, and dismisses the appeal; finds the appellants liable in expenses; allows an account thereof to be given in; and remits the same to the Auditor of Court to tax and report, and decerns.”
Baird and Brown appealed to the Court of Session.
Solicitor-General and Orr Paterson for them, argued—That the ranking of the creditors must be regulated by the principles which have been long established, and explained by Bell in his Commentaries (vol. ii, p. 407, &c., 7th ed), viz.—(1) that no person is to suffer by the use of inhibition except the persons against whom it is used; (2) that no person is to be benefited by the inhibition except the person who has used it. The only way in which these principles can be carried out is by first ranking all the creditors pari passu on the proceeds of the heritable estate, and then giving the inhibiting creditor the difference between what he thus draws and what he would have drawn had no debts been contracted subsequent to his inhibition, by way of drawback on the dividends of the posterior creditors, i.e. those whose claims are affected by the inhibition.
It must be observed that the use of inhibition does not prevent adjudication by subsequent creditors, any more than it prevents a voluntary security being created. It prevents any subsequent debt from affecting the heritable estate to the prejudice of the inhibitor, but it will not prevent a subsequent creditor from obtaining a security preferable to those who have not adjudged. In short, the sole effect of the inhibition is to enable the inhibitor to rank on the heritable estate as if no debts had been contracted after the inhibition.
I have no doubt that this appeal is competent. The deliverance of the trustee, whilst admitting generally the claims of the creditors, lays down a
Page: 252↓
On the merits, the question is raised by the circumstance of one of the creditors having used inhibition on his debt some months anterior to the sequestration; this inhibition being posterior to the contraction of some of the debts, and anterior to the contraction of others. The main question is, how this inhibition tells on the distribution of certain heritable estate belonging to the bankrupts, which has been sold, and the proceeds of which are included in the fund of division.
By the 107th section of the Bankrupt statute, 19 and 20 Vict. c. 79, it is declared that “the sequestration shall, as at the date thereof, be equivalent to a decree of adjudication of the heritable estates of the bankrupt for payment of the whole debts of the bankrupt, principal and interest, accumulated at the said date.” The effect of this enactment is to place all the creditors in the position of adjudging creditors, having a pari passu ranking at the date of sequestration; but subject to any preferences inter se by inhibition or otherwise. In the present case there are (1) the creditors anterior to the inhibition, being in law adjudging creditors on the heritable estate; (2) the inhibiting creditor, who is an adjudging creditor, but who has also an inhibition; (3) the posterior creditors, who are equally adjudging creditors with the others, but whose debts are struck at by the inhibition.
In such a case the grand principle of ranking is to give full effect to the preferential or exclusive right, but only to give it effect in favour of those to whom its benefit enures by law, and not in favour of others who have no right to found on it. In the present case the inhibition gives the inhibiting creditor a full right of preference against the posterior creditors, entitling him to be put in the same position in a question with these as if their debts did not exist at all. But the inhibition gives the inhibitor no preference over the anterior creditors, at whose debts it does not strike. Further, the inhibition gives no right of preference to the anterior creditors other than the inhibitor, for by them or for their behoof it was not used; and in any question with these the posterior creditors are entitled to a pari passu ranking, being all equally adjudging creditors. The proper mode of ranking is therefore that which gives the benefit of the inhibition only to the inhibiting creditor, and leaves matters as to the others as if no inhibition had been used.
How to accomplish such a ranking was for a while a difficulty in our law; a difficulty at least as old as the case of the Creditors of Langton in 1709, Mor. 2877. But a formula of ranking was at last laid down, which I consider quite settled. It is explained by Mr Erskine in Book II. tit. 12, sec. 32; and more fully and clearly by Mr Bell in his Commentaries, 2d volume, from p. 402 (last edition) onwards. At p. 413 he thus lays down the primary canons of ranking—“(1) That the first operation in the ranking and division is to set aside for each of the creditors who hold real securities the dividend to which his real right entitles him, without regard to the exclusive preference. (2) That the rights of exclusion are then to be applied in the way of drawback, from the dividends of those creditors whose real securities are affected by them, taking care that they do not encroach on the dividends of other creditors. (3) That the holder of such exclusive right is entitled thus to draw back the difference between what he draws upon the first division and what he would have drawn had the claims struck at by the inhibition not existed.” These canons of ranking I consider so firmly established and so trite that I almost wonder at their having been overlooked in the present case.
Applying these canons in the present case, the proper mode of ranking involves the following process. The proceeds of the heritable estate are first tentatively divided among all the creditors pari passu, as all equally adjudging creditors, having a pari passu ranking. This would be the mode of ranking if no inhibition existed; and it fixes the rights of the anterior creditors and the inhibiting creditor inter se, because the interests of these are not affected by the inhibition. Under the second step in the process, the ranking is made as if the posterior creditors did not exist at all. This of course shows an increased ranking to both anterior creditors and inhibitor. But the anterior creditors cannot take advantage of it, because they have no right of preference over the posterior creditors. The benefit belongs alone to the inhibitor. The third step accordingly is, that the inhibitor draws back from the posterior creditors the difference between an equal dividend to all, and the enlarged dividend which he would have individually drawn had no posterior creditors existed. There is thus brought out the true order of ranking. The anterior creditors get their proper ranking, which is pari passu with all. The inhibitor gets the benefit of his inhibition, which he draws back from the posterior creditors, at whose debts the inhibition strikes. The posterior creditors suffer the defalcation brought upon them by the inhibition, but only in a question with the inhibitor, not with the anterior creditors, who have no preference over them.
The arithmetical result was very clearly and accurately stated in the course of the argument. Suppose that the debts of the three classes were each class of equal amount, and that on a pari passu ranking of all the dividend is 10s. per pound. This represents the dividend which will belong to the anterior creditors, who have no right except to a pari passu ranking with all. But if the posterior creditors had not existed the inhibitor would have drawn 15s. per pound, because the 30s. which is divided, in the pari passu ranking of all, to the extent of 10s. to each class, would have been in that case shared in the proportion of 15s. each, between the anterior creditors and the inhibitor. In other words, the inhibiting creditor would have had one-half, in place of one-third. The difference, or 5s. per pound, is drawn back by the inhibitor from the postponed creditors. The ranking then stands—anterior creditors, 10s. per pound; inhibiting creditor, 15s. per pound; posterior creditors, 5s. per pound.
The trustee and Sheriff have not followed this method of ranking, but one wholly different. It is unnecessary to go into details. The admitted sub
Page: 253↓
The deliverance and interlocutor must therefore be altered, to the effect of remitting to the trustee to rank the creditors on the heritable estate according to the formula above referred to.
With regard to the ranking on the general or moveable estate, which is also involved in the trustee's scheme, there is no difficulty. The creditors are, in regard to the moveables, all in the same predicament. They are therefore to be ranked pari passu, subject to the qualification that all holding a preferable security over the heritable estate must value and deduct the value of the security, in terms of the Bankrupt statute. The amount will of course be easy to state, after the ranking on the heritable estate is fixed, for the amount of that ranking will denote the deduction.
On the merits, the interlocutor of the Sheriff requires most attentive consideration. Few men are better acquainted with the subject than he. But after much consideration I have come to be entirely of the opinion of Lord Kinloch. I think that the law, clearly expressed by Mr Bell, must be held as established, and even if the question could be considered open, I should have come to the same conclusion. There is no adjudication prior to or apart from the sequestration. The sequestration operates on an adjudication, but for behoof of all the creditors, and does not disturb the rights of creditors inter se. The inhibition affects no rights except those which it strikes at, and gives no right except to the inhibitor.
Lord President—I should be sorry if the decision of the Court in a question of such importance should be thought to rest in any degree on the admission of counsel in argument. My opinion is not influenced by any such considerations. I concur entirely in the opinion of Lord Kinloch, as expressing a perfectly well settled rule of ranking, clearly applicable to this case. The rule was established without reference to a sequestration, and very naturally, because it was established before the introduction of the process of sequestration. The rule contemplates an inhibiting creditor, creditors whose debts were contracted prior to the inhibition, and creditors whose debts were contracted subsequent to the inhibition. All those creditors adjudge within year and day of one another, so that it does not matter which is the leading adjudication. In respect of their adjudications they all rank pari passu. But the inhibiting creditor has a preference over those whose debts were contracted subsequent to the inhibition. The prior creditors are to be neither hurt nor benefited by the inhibition. In these circumstances the clear and equitable rule of ranking was established, that the inhibitor's preference must be secured to him at the expense of the subsequent creditors, while creditors whose debts were contracted prior to the inhibition draw just what they would have done had the whole creditors been ranked pari passu. Lord Deas has
Page: 254↓
The Court pronounced the following interlocutor:—“Recal the deliverance of the trustee and interlocutor of the Sheriff complained of; Find that the order of ranking of the creditors on the proceeds of the heritable estate is to be ascertained as follows: First, the whole creditors are to be ranked pari passu as adjudging creditors on the said proceeds; and the dividend thereby arising is to be held the dividend payable to these creditors whose debts were contracted anterior to the use of the inhibition; Secondly, for the purpose of ascertaining the dividend payable to the inhibiting creditors, the said anterior creditors and the inhibiting creditors shall be ranked pari passu on the said proceeds, as if no debts had been contracted subsequently to the use of the inhibition, and the inhibiting creditor shall drawback from the posterior creditors the difference between the dividend arising on the first pari passu ranking and that arising on the second ranking, and the said difference, added to the dividend arising on the said pari passu ranking, shall be held the dividend payable to the said inhibiting creditors. Third, the dividend on the said pari passu ranking, less the amount so drawn back by the inhibiting creditors, shall be held the dividend payable to the posterior creditors: Find that all the creditors are entitled to be ranked pari passu on the proceeds of the moveable estate, each of the said creditors valuing and deducting the value of any security held over any part of the bankrupt estate in terms of law: Remit to the trustee to frame a scheme of ranking in accordance with these findings, and decern: Find the appellants entitled to expenses both in this Court and in the Sheriff-court: Allow accounts,” &c.
Solicitors: Agents for Appellants— J. & A. Peddie, W.S.
Agents for Respondent— J. & R. Macandrew, W.S.