BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
United Kingdom House of Lords Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> United Kingdom House of Lords Decisions >> Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper's Garage (Stourport) Ltd [1967] UKHL 1 (23 February 1967) URL: http://www.bailii.org/uk/cases/UKHL/1967/1.html Cite as: [1967] UKHL 1, [1968] AC 269 |
[New search] [Buy ICLR report: [1968] AC 269] [Help]
Parliamentary
Archives,
HL/PO/JU/4/3/1152
HOUSE OF LORDS
ESSO PETROLEUM COMPANY LIMITED
v.
HARPER'S GARAGE (STOURPORT) LIMITED
Lord Reid
Lord
Morris of
Borth-y-Gest
Lord Hodson
Lord Pearce
Lord
Wilberforce
Lord Reid
my lords,
The
Appellants are a large company whose most important product is
Esso
petrol most of which is sold by them to garages and filling
stations
for resale to the public. The Respondent Company own two
garages: they
contracted with the Appellants under what are know
as solus agreements
and bound themselves for the periods of those
agreements inter alia to
sell at their garages Esso petrol
and no other. When cheaper " cut price "
petrol came on
the market they began to sell it and ceased to sell Esso
petrol.
The Appellants then raised two actions, now consolidated, to
prevent
this: they sought injunctions to restrain the Respondents
from buying other
than from them any motor fuel for resale at
these garages. On 17th March,
1955 Mocatta, J. granted an
injunction, but on appeal the Court of Appeal
set aside this order
on the ground that the ties in these agreements were in
restraint
of trade and were unenforceable. The Appellants now maintain
first
that these ties were not in restraint of trade and secondly that, if
they
were, they were in the circumstances valid and enforceable.
The
earlier agreement related to the Corner Garage, Stourport, and was
to
remain in force for 21 years from 1st July, 1962. But, as the
case with
regard to it is complicated by there being a mortgage in
security for money
lent by the Appellants to the Respondents, I
shall first consider the second
agreement which related to the
Mustow Green Garage near Kidderminster.
This agreement was to
remain in force for four years and five months from
1st July,
1963. It appears that the Appellants had a similar agreement with
the
previous owners of that garage and that this period was chosen
because
it was the unexpired period of that earlier agreement.
The main
provisions of the Mustow Green agreement are that while it
remained
in force the Respondents agreed to buy from the Appellants
their
total requirements of motor fuels for resale at that garage
and agreed to
keep it open at all reasonable hours for the sale of
Esso Motor Fuels and
Esso Motor oils, and in return the Appellants
agreed to sell to the Respon-
dents at their wholesale schedule
price at the time of delivery, and to
allow a rebate from that
price of one penny farthing per gallon payable
quarterly. There
were a number of other provisions with regard to advertis-
ing,
service at the garage etc. which I shall not specify because they do
not
appear to me to assist in determining the questions at issue.
But there are
two other provisions which I must notice. If the
Respondents wished to dis-
pose of the garage they were not to do
so except to a person who agreed to
be substituted for them for
all purposes of this agreement. If the agreement
is otherwise
unobjectionable I do not think that this provision can invalidate
it
because it was only by some such means that the Appellants could
ensure
that their petrol would continue to be sold at this garage
for the full period
of the agreement. The other is a provision for
retail price maintenance
which the Appellants at that time
inserted in all their numerous tieing
agreements with garages and
filling stations. Shortly before the present
action was raised the
Appellants intimated that they would not enforce
this clause
against any of their tied customers. The Respondents were in
favour
of retail price maintenance and their original defence was that
this
change of policy by the Appellants entitled them to rescind
the whole
agreement for the tie. This defence was rejected by
Mocatta, J. and it
has not been maintained before your Lordships.
So I can
now turn to the first question in this appeal—whether this
agree-
ment is to be regarded in law as an agreement in restraint
of trade. The
law with regard to restraint of trade is of ancient
origin. There are refer-
ences to it in the Year Books and it
seems to have received considerable
2
attention
in the time of Queen Elizabeth I. But the old cases lie within
a
narrow compass. It seems to have been common for an apprentice
or a
craftsman to agree with his master that he would not compete
with him
after leaving his service, and also for a trader who sold
his business to
agree that he would not thereafter compete with
the purchaser of his business.
But no early case was cited which
did not fall within one or other of these
categories. And even in
recent times there have been surprisingly few
reported cases
falling outside these categories in which restraint of trade has
been
pleaded: we were informed by Counsel that there are only about
forty
English cases which can be traced. On the other hand there
is an immense
body of authorities with regard to the two original
categories. I have not
found it an easy task to determine how far
principles developed for the
original categories have been or
should be extended.
The most
general statement with regard to restraint of trade is that of
Lord
Parker in Commonwealth of Australia v. Adelaide Steamship
Com-
pany [1913] AC 781 at page 794. He said: "
Monopolies and contracts in
" restraint of trade have this in
common, that they both, if enforced, involve
" a derogation
from the common law right in virtue of which any member
" of
the community may exercise any trade or business he pleases and in
"
such manner as he thinks best in his own interests ". But that
cannot
have been intended to be a definition: all contracts in
restraint of trade
involve such a derogation but not all contracts
involving such a derogation
are contracts in restraint of trade.
Whenever a man agrees to do something
over a period he thereby
puts it wholly or partly out of his power to " exer-
"
cise any trade or business he pleases " during that period. He
may enter
into a contract of service or may agree to give his
exclusive services to
another: then during the period of the
contract he is not entitled to engage
in other business
activities. But no one has ever suggested that such con-
tracts
are in restraint of trade except in very unusual circumstances, such
as
those in Young v. Timmins (1831) C. & J. 331
where the servant had agreed
not to work for anyone else but might
have been given no work and
received no remuneration for
considerable periods and thus have been
deprived of a livelihood:
the grounds of judgment may not now be correct
but I think that
the case was rightly decided.
That Lord
Parker cannot have intended those words to be a definition
is I
think made clear by a passage lower on the same page of the report:
"
Contracts in restraint of trade were subject to somewhat different
"
considerations. There is little doubt that the common law in the
"
earlier stages of its growth treated all" (my italics) "
such contracts
" as contracts of imperfect obligation, if not
void for all purposes; they
" were said to be against public
policy in the sense that it was deemed
" impolitic to enforce
them."
He
certainly never supposed that all contracts which by obliging a man
to
act in one way (e.g. as a servant) prevented him from doing
other things
had ever been held to be of imperfect obligation or
against public policy.
The
leading case of Nordenfelt v. Maxim Nordenfelt Guns [1894]
A.C.
535 fell within the old categories, and it may be misleading
to take the well-
known passages out of context and try to apply
them to cases of quite
different nature. Lord Macnaghten said at
page 565:
" The
public have an interest in every person's carrying on his trade
"
freely: so has the individual. All interference with individual
liberty
" of action in trading, and all restraints of trade
of themselves, if there
" is nothing more, are contrary to
public policy, and therefore void."
By "
interference " he meant interference to which the individual had
agreed
by contract but I am sure that he did not mean to include
all cases in
which one party had " interfered " with the
liberty of another by getting him
to agree to give his whole time
to the other party's affairs. He had said
(on page 564):
" In
the age of Queen Elizabeth all restraints of trade, whatever they
"
were, general or partial, were thought to be contrary to public
policy,
" and therefore void."
3
So he only
had in mind the two original kinds of case. There was no
need in
Nordenfelt's case to attempt to define other classes of case
to which
the doctrine of restraint would apply.
If a
contract is within the class of contracts in restraint of trade the
law
which applies to it is quite different from the law which
applies to contracts
generally. In general unless a contract is
vitiated by duress fraud or mistake
its terms will be enforced
though unreasonable or even harsh and uncon-
scionable, but here a
term in restraint of trade will not be enforced unless
it is
reasonable. And in the ordinary case the Court will not remake
a
contract: unless in the special case where the contract is
severable, it
will not strike out one provision as unenforceable
and enforce the rest. But
here the party who has been paid for
agreeing to the restraint may be
unjustly enriched if the Court
holds the restraint to be too wide to be
enforceable and is unable
to adjust the consideration given by the other
party.
It is much
too late now to say that this rather anomalous doctrine of
restraint
of trade can be confined to the two classes of case to which it
was
originally applied. But the cases outside these two classes
afford little
guidance as to the circumstances in which it should
be applied. In some it
has been assumed that the doctrine applies
and the controversy has been
whether the restraint was reasonable.
And in others where one might have
expected the point to be taken
it was not taken, perhaps because Counsel
thought that there was
no chance of the Court holding that the restraint was
too wide to
be reasonable.
In
McEllistrim v. Ballymacelligott Co-operative Society [1919]
A.C. 548
the Society had changed its rules so as to prevent any
member from selling
(except under heavy penalty) any milk produced
by him in a large area of
County Kerry to anyone except the
Society, and a member could not terminate
his membership without
the Society's permission. The plaintiff, who was a
member, sought
a declaration that the new rules were in unreasonable restraint
of
trade. Lord Birkenhead, L.C., assumed that they were in restraint
of
trade and held that they were unreasonable, as did Lord
Atkinson and Lord
Shaw. Lord Finlay said (at page 571), having
referred to Morris v. Saxelby
[1916] I A.C. 688:
"The present case is really governed by the principle
"
there enunciated that ' public policy requires that every man shall
be at
" ' liberty to work for himself and shall not be at
liberty to deprive himself
" ' or the State of his labour,
skill or talent, by any contract that he enters
" ' into '.
This is equally applicable to the right to sell his goods ". I
doubt
whether this last sentence is quite accurate. It would seem
to mean that
every contract by which a man (or a company) agrees
to sell his whole output
(or even half of it) for any future
period to the other party to the contract
is a contract in
restraint of trade because it restricts his liberty to sell as
he
pleases, and is therefore unenforceable unless his agreement
can be justified
as being reasonable. There must have been many
ordinary commercial
contracts of that kind in the past but no one
has ever suggested that they
were in restraint of trade. But
McEllistrim's case at least establishes that
there comes a
point at which such a contract can come within the doctrine
of
restraint of trade.
In English
Hop Growers v. Dering [1928] 2 K.B. 174 the defendant
had
agreed to sell his crop of hops to the Society for five years.
He failed to do
so and was sued: in defence he pleaded that the
contract was in restraint
of trade. The restraint was held to be
reasonable but both Scrutton, L.J.,
and the other Members of the
Court appear to have been prepared to treat
this as a contract in
restraint of trade. This was not just an ordinary agree-
ment, it
was rather a marketing scheme accepted by the great majority
of
English hop growers.
In Foley
v. Classique Coaches [1934] 2 K.B. 1 the purchaser of a
piece of
land agreed with the seller to take from him all the
petrol required for the
purchaser's business carried on there. The
question whether this was in
restraint of trade was dealt with
briefly, Scrutton, L.J., merely saying that
it was not in "
undue restraint of trade ". In Servais Bouchard v.
Princes
Hall Restaurant [1904] 20 T.L.R. 574 the Court of
Appeal held valid a
4
contract
by which the Restaurant agreed to take all burgundy sold there
from
the plaintiffs. It is not very clear whether they held that
this was not in
restraint of trade or that, though in restraint of
trade, it was reasonable.
In United
Shoe Machinery Company of Canada v. Brunet [1909] AC 330
the Company leased machinery under a condition that it should
not be used
in conjunction with machinery made by any other
manufacturer, and it was
held that this condition was not in
restraint of trade. I do not think that
the reasons given for the
decision are very satisfactory. Mogul Steamship Com-
pany v.
McGregor Gow & Co. [1892] AC 25 is relied on. There an
associa-
tion of shipowners agreed to use various lawful means to
dissuade customers
from shipping their goods by the Mogul line. It
was held that this agree-
ment was lawful in the sense that it
gave the Mogul Company no right to
sue them. But it was recognised
at least by the majority of their Lordships
that the agreement
would have been unenforceable as between the members
of the
association. Lord Watson said (at page 42) " an agreement by
traders
" to combine for a lawful purpose, and for a
specified time, is not binding
" upon any of the parties to
it if he chooses to withdraw, and consequently
" cannot be
enforced in invitum ". One must always bear in mind that
an
agreement in restraint of trade is not generally unlawful if
the parties choose
to abide by it: it is only unenforceable if a
party chooses not to abide by it.
The main
argument submitted for the Appellant on this matter was
that
restraint of trade means a personal restraint and does not
apply to a restraint
on the use of a particular piece of land.
Otherwise, it was said, every
covenant running with the land which
prevents its use for all or for some
trading purposes would be a
covenant in restraint of trade and therefore
unenforceable unless
it could be shown to be reasonable and for the protec-
tion of
some legitimate interest. It was said that the present agreement
only
prevents the sale of petrol from other suppliers on the site
of the Mustow
Green garage: It leaves the Respondents free to
trade anywhere else in any
way they choose. But in many cases a
trader trading at a particular place
does not have the resources
to enable him to begin trading elsewhere as
well, and if he did he
might find it difficult to find another suitable garage
for sale
or to get planning permission to open a new filling station
on
another site. As the whole doctrine of restraint of trade is
based on public
policy its application ought to depend less on
legal niceties or theoretical
possibilities than on the practical
effect of a restraint in hampering that
freedom which it is the
policy of the law to protect.
It is true
that it would be an innovation to hold that ordinary
negative
covenants preventing the use of a particular site for
trading of all kinds
or of a particular kind are within the scope
of the doctrine of restraint of
trade. I do not think they are.
Restraint of trade appears to me to imply
that a man contracts
to give up some freedom which otherwise he would
have had. A
person buying or leasing land had no previous right to be
there at
all, let alone to trade there, and when he takes possession of
that
land subject to a negative restrictive covenant he gives up
no right or freedom
which he previously had. I think that the "
tied house " cases might be
explained in this way, apart from
Biggs v. Hoddinott [1898] 2 Ch 307 where
the owner
of a freehouse had agreed to a tie in favour of a brewer who
had
lent him money. Restraint of trade was not pleaded. If it had
been
the restraint would probably have been held to be reasonable.
But there
is some difficulty if a restraint in a lease not
merely prevents the person
who takes possession of the land under
the lease from doing certain things
there, but also obliges him to
act in a particular way. In the present case
the Respondents
before they made this agreement were entitled to use this
land in
any lawful way they chose, and by making this agreement they
agreed
to restrict their right by giving up their right to sell there petrol
not
supplied by the Appellants.
In my view
this agreement is within the scope of the doctrine of restraint
of
trade as it had been developed in English law. Not only have
the
Respondents agreed negatively not to sell other petrol but
they have agreed
positively to keep this garage open for the sale
of the Appellants' petrol at
all reasonable hours throughout the
period of the tie. It was argued that
5
this was
merely regulating the Respondent's trading and rather promoting
than
restraining his trade. But regulating a person's existing trade may
be
a greater restraint than prohibiting him from engaging in a new
trade. And
a contract to take one's whole supply from one source
may be much more
hampering than a contract to sell one's whole
output to one buyer. I would
not attempt to define the dividing
line between contracts which are and
contracts which are not in
restraint of trade, but in my view this contract
(must be held to
be in restraint of trade. So it is necessary to consider
whether
its provisions can be justified.
But before
considering this question I must deal briefly with the
other
agreement tying the Corner Garage for 21 years. The rebate
and other
advantages to the Respondents were similar to those in
the Mustow Green
agreement but in addition the Appellants made a
loan of £7,000 to the
Respondents to enable them to improve
their garage and this loan was to
be repaid over the 21 years of
the tie. In security they took a mortgage
of this garage. The
agreement provided that the loan should not be paid
off earlier
than at the dates stipulated. But the Respondents now tender
the
unpaid balance of the loan and they say that the Appellants have
no
interest to refuse to accept repayment now except in order to
maintain the
tie for the full 21 years.
The
Appellants argue that the fact that there is a mortgage excludes
any
application of the doctrine of restraint of trade. But I agree
with your
Lordships in rejecting that argument. I am prepared to
assume that, if
the Respondents had not offered to repay the loan
so far as it is still out-
standing, the Appellants would have
been entitled to retain the tie. But,
as they have tendered
repayment, I do not think that the existence of the
loan and the
mortgage puts the Appellants in any stronger position to
maintain
the tie than they would have been in if the original agreements
had
permitted repayment at an earlier date. The Appellants must shew
that
in the circumstances when the agreement was made a tie for 21
years was
justifiable.
It is now
generally accepted that a provision in a contract which is to
be
regarded as in restraint of trade must be justified if it is to
be enforceable,
and that the law on this matter was correctly
stated by Lord Macnaghten in
the Nordenfelt case. He said:
"
Restraints of trade and interference with individual liberty of
action
" may be justified by the special circumstances of a
particular case. It is
" a sufficient justification, and
indeed it is the only justification, if the
" restriction is
reasonable—reasonable, that is, in reference to the interests
"
of the parties concerned and reasonable in reference to the
interests
" of the public, so framed and so guarded as to
afford adequate protec-
" tion to the party in whose favour
it is imposed, while at the same
" time it is in no way
injurious to the public."
So in
every case it is necessary to consider first whether the restraint
went
farther than to afford adequate protection to the party in
whose favour it
was granted, secondly whether it can be justified
as being in the interests of
the party restrained, and thirdly
whether it must be held contrary to the
public interest. I find it
difficult to agree with the way in which the Court
has in some
cases treated the interests of the party restrained. Surely it
can
never be in the interest of a person to agree to suffer a
restraint unless he gets
some compensating advantage, direct or
indirect. And Lord Macnaghten
said " of course the quantum of
consideration may enter into the question
" of the
reasonableness of the contract ".
Where
two experienced traders are bargaining on equal terms and one
has
agreed to a restraint for reasons which seem good to him the
Court is in
grave danger of stultifying itself if it says that it
knows that trader's interest
better than he does himself. But
there may well be cases where, although the
party to be restrained
has deliberately accepted the main terms of the contract,
he has
been at a disadvantage as regards other terms: for example where
a
set of conditions has been incorporated which has not been the
subject
of negotiation—there the Court may have greater
freedom to hold them
unreasonable.
6
I think
that in some cases where the Court has held that a restraint was
not
in the interests of the parties it would have been more correct to
hold
that the restraint was against the public interest. For
example in Kores v.
Kolok [1959] 1 Ch. 108 the
parties had agreed that neither would employ
any man who had left
the service of the other. From their own points
of view there was
probably very good reason for that. But it could well be
held to
be against the public interest to interfere in this way with the
freedom
of their employees. If the parties chose to abide by their
agreement an
employee would have no more right to complain than
the Mogul Company
had in the Mogul case. But the law would
not countenance their agreement
by enforcing it. And in cases
where a party, who is in no way at a disad-
vantage in bargaining,
chooses to take a calculated risk, I see no reason why
the Court
should say that he has acted against his own interests: but it
can
say that the restraint might well produce a situation which
would be contrary
to the public interest.
Again,
whether or not a restraint is in the personal interests of the
parties,
it is I think well established that the Court will not
enforce a restraint which
goes farther than affording adequate
protection to the legitimate interests
of the party in whose
favour it is granted. This must I think be because too
wide a
restraint is against the public interest. It has often been said
that
a person is not entitled to be protected against mere
competition. I do not
find that very helpful in a case like the
present. I think it better to ascertain
what were the legitimate
interests of the Appellants which they were entitled
to protect
and then to see whether these restraints were more than adequate
for
that purpose.
What were
the Appellants' legitimate interests must depend largely on what
was
the state of affairs in their business and with regard to the
distribution
and sale of petrol generally. And those are questions
of fact to be answered
by evidence or common knowledge. In the
present case restraint of trade
was not pleaded originally and the
Appellants only received notice that it
was to be raised a
fortnight before the trial. They may have been wise in
not seeking
a postponement of the trial when the pleadings were amended.
But
the result has been that the evidence on this matter is scanty. I
think
however that it is legitimate to supplement it from the
considerable body of
reported cases regarding solus agreements and
from the facts found in the
Report of the Monopolies Commission of
July, 1965.
When
petrol rationing came to an end in 1950 the large producers began
to
make agreements, now known as solus agreements, with garage
owners
under which the garage owner, in return for certain
advantages, agreed to sell
only the petrol of the producer with
whom he made the agreement. Within
a short time three-quarters of
the filling stations in this country were tied in
that way and by
the dates of the agreements in this case over 90 per cent,
had
agreed to ties. It appears that the garage owners were not at a
disad-
vantage in bargaining with the large producing companies as
there was
intense competition between these companies to obtain
these ties. So we
can assume that both the garage owners and the
companies thought that
such ties were to their advantage. And it
is not said in this case that all ties
are either against the
public interest or against the interests of the parties.
The
Respondents' case is that the ties with which we are concerned are
for
too long periods.
The
advantage to the garage owner is that he gets a rebate on the
whole-
sale price of the petrol which he buys and also may get
other benefits or
financial assistance. The main advantages for
the producing company
appear to be that distribution is made
easier and more economical and
that it is assured of a steady
outlet for its petrol over a period. As regards
distribution it
appears that there were some 35,000 filling stations in this
country
at the relevant time, of which about a fifth were tied to the
Appel-
lants. So they only have to distribute to some 7,000 filing
stations instead
of to a very much larger number if most filling
stations sold several brands
of petrol. But the main reason why
the producing companies want ties
for five years and more instead
of ties for one or two years only seems to
7
be that
they can organise their business better if on the average only
one-
fifth or less of their ties come to an end in any one year.
The Appellants
make a point of the fact that they have invested
some £200 millions in
refineries and other plant and that
they could not have done that unless
they could foresee a steady
and assured level of sales of their petrol. Most
of their ties
appear to have been made for periods of between five and
twenty
years. But we have no evidence as to the precise additional
advan-
tage which they derive from a five year tie as compared
with a two year
tie or from a twenty years tie as compared with a
five year tie.
The Court
of Appeal held that these ties were for unreasonably long
periods.
They thought that, if for any reason the Respondents ceased to
sell
the Appellants' petrol, the Appellants could have found other
suitable
outlets in the neighbourhood within two or three years. I
do not think
that that is the right test. In the first place there
was no evidence about
this and I do not think that it would be
practicable to apply this test in
practice. It might happen that
when the Respondents ceased to sell their
petrol, the Appellants
would find such an alternative outlet in a very
short time. But,
looking to the fact that well over 90 per cent, of existing
filling
stations are tied and that there may be great difficulty in opening
a
new filling station, it might take a very long time to find an
alternative. Any
estimate of how long it might take to find
suitable alternatives for the
Respondents' filling stations could
be little better than guesswork.
I do not
think that the Appellants' interest can be regarded so narrowly.
They
are not so much concerned with any particular outlet as with
main-
taining a stable system of distribution throughout the
country so as to
enable their business to be run efficiently and
economically. In my view
there is sufficient material to justify a
decision that ties of less than five years
were insufficient, in
the circumstances of the trade when these agreements
were made, to
afford adequate protection to the Appellants' legitimate
interests.
And if that is so I cannot find anything in the details of the
Mustow
Green agreement which would indicate that it is unreasonable.
It
is true that if some of the provisions were operated by the
Appellants
in a manner which would be commercially unreasonable
they might put the
Respondents in difficulties. But I think that a
Court must have regard
to the fact that the Appellants must act in
such a way that they will be able
to obtain renewals of the great
majority of their very numerous ties some of
which will come to an
end almost every week. If in such circumstances
a garage owner
chooses to rely on the commercial probity and good sense
of the
producer I do not think that a Court should hold his
agreement
unreasonable because it is legally capable of some
misuse. I would there-
fore allow the appeal as regards the Mustow
Green agreement.
But
the Corner Garage agreement involves much more difficulty.
Taking
first the legitimate interests of the Appellants, a new
argument was submitted
to your Lordships that, apart from any
question of security for their loan,
it would be unfair to the
Appellants if the Respondents, having used the
Appellants' money
to build up their business, were entitled after a com-
paratively
short time to be free to seek better terms from a competing
producer.
But there is no material on which I can assess the strength of
this
argument and I do not find myself in a position to determine
whether
it has any validity. A tie for twenty-one years stretches
far beyond any
period for which developments are reasonably
foreseeable. Restrictions
on the garage owner which might seem
tolerable and reasonable in reason-
ably foreseeable conditions
might come to have a very different effect in
quite different
conditions: the public interest comes in here more strongly.
And,
apart from a case where he gets a loan, a garage owner appears to
get
no greater advantage from a twenty year tie than he gets from a five
year
tie. So I would think that there must at least be some
clearly established
advantage to the producing company—something
to show that a shorter
period would not be adequate—before
so long a period could be justified.
But in this case there is no
evidence to prove anything of the kind. And
the other material
which I have thought it right to consider does not appear
to me to
assist the Appellant here. I would therefore dismiss the appeal
as
regards the Corner Garage agreement.
8
I would
add that the decision in this case—particularly in view of
the
paucity of evidence—ought not in my view to be regarded
as laying down
any general rule as to the length of tie
permissible in a solus agreement.
And I do not think that the case
of Petrofina v. Martin [1966] Ch. 146 can
be regarded as
laying down a general rule. The agreement there was in un-
usual
terms. I think the decision was right although I do not agree
with
all the reasons. But I must not be taken as expressing any
opinion as to the
validity of ties for periods mid-way between the
two periods with which
the present case is concerned.
Lord Morris of Borth-y-Gest
MY LORDS,
We have
been concerned in this case to decide as to the application
of
competing principles of law. In a system of law not contained
in any
formal code decision is reached by applying settled or
recognised principle
to particular ascertained facts. But in some
situations more than one prin-
ciple may be relevant and
important. Particularly is this so where principles
have, as their
foundation, the dictates of public policy. That has been so
in the
case of those which have been prominent in the arguments in
this
case. The Respondent Company (Harpers) assert, while the
Appellants
(Esso), deny that what is generally called the "
doctrine " of restraint of trade
must be considered in
reference to the solus agreements: if so, then the
agreements must
pass a test of reasonableness before they can qualify to
be
enforceable. Whether the doctrine must be considered and, if so,
with
what result is now the effective issue in the litigation,
though it was not at
first raised and, indeed, only emerged as an
issue on the eve or at the
commencement of the trial.
The law
has for many centuries set itself against restraint of
trade.
Monopolies, likewise, have always been in disfavour with
the law. In
keeping with this, arrangements are condemned
which have as their mere
purpose the elimination of competition.
Restraints which would result in
preventing a man from pursuing
his trade and earning his living may be
injurious to the man
himself and to a family dependent on his support and
may be
detrimental to the public interest. (See Mitchel v. Reynolds
1 Peere
Williams 181.) The abhorrence of such restraints
can be strong enough
to prevail over certain well accepted
principles. In general the law recognises
that there is freedom
to enter into any contract that can lawfully be made.
The law
lends its weight to uphold and enforce contracts freely entered
into.
The law does not allow a man to derogate from his grant.
If
someone has sold the goodwill of his business some restraint to
enable
the purchaser to have that which he has bought may be
recognised as
reasonable. Some restraints to ensure
the protection of confidential
information may be similarly
regarded. The law recognises that if business
contracts are
fairly made by parties who are on equal terms such parties
should
know their business best. If there has been no irregularity the
law
does not mend or amend contracts merely for the relief of
those for whom
things have not turned out well. But when all
this is fully recognised yet
the law, in some circumstances,
reserves a right to say that a contract is
in restraint of trade
and that to be enforceable it must pass a test of
reasonableness.
In the competition between varying principles
possible
applicable that which makes certain covenants in
restraint of trade unenforce-
able will in some circumstances be
strong enough to prevail. Public policy
will give it priority.
It will have such priority because of the reasonable
necessity to
ensure and preserve freedom of trade. Some words spoken by
Sir
George Jessell M.R. in Printing and Numerical Registering Co.
v.
Sampson L.R. 19 Eq. 462, may, however, be kept in
mind. At page 465
he said: —
" It
must not be forgotten that you are not to extend arbitrarily
"
those rules which say that a given contract is void as being
against
" public policy, because if there is one thing which
more than another
9
"
public policy requires it is that men of full age and competent
under-
" standing shall have the utmost liberty of
contracting, and that their
" contracts when entered into
freely and voluntarily shall be held
" sacred and shall be
enforced by Courts of Justice. Therefore, you
" have this
paramount public policy to consider—that you are not
"
lightly to interfere with this freedom of contract."
To a
similar purport were some words by Scrutton L.J. in his judgment
in
English Hop Growers Ltd. v. Dering [1928] 2 K.B.
174, when at page 181
he said: —
" I
have always myself regarded it as in the public interest that
"
parties who, being in an equal position of bargaining, make
contracts,
" should be compelled to perform them, and not to
escape from their
" liabilities by saying that they had
agreed to something which was
" unreasonable."
While
accepting the power and weight of these observations it can
be
remembered that, even if a contract is in restraint of trade,
it will never-
theless be enforceable provided always that the
restriction is reasonable in
reference to the interest of the
parties and in reference to the interest of
the public. Though a
person has not been under any compulsion nor has
laboured under
any deception when making a contract under which he
agrees to a
restraint in trade yet in some circumstances the law allows him
to
seek to defend himself from compliance with the terms of the
restraint
by inviting the Court to say that the contract should
not be enforced.
As,
therefore, the policy of the law is to uphold freedom to contract
and
also to uphold freedom to trade a certain adjustment is
necessary. In his
speech in Herbert Morris Limited v.
Saxelby [1916] 1 A.C. 688 Lord Shaw
at page 716 said: —
" The
delicacy of the operation of law in settling the bounds of either
"
freedom has long been familiar. In these cases, as I have pointed
out,
" there are two freedoms to be considered—one the
freedom of trade
" and the other the freedom of contract: and
to that I will now again
" venture to add that it is a
mistake to think that public interest is only
" concerned
with one: it is concerned with both."
The
enquiry is raised as to what are the circumstances in which
the
doctrine applies. In particular in the present case the
question arises whether
it can be said that the solus agreements
by their terms involve a restraint
of trade. If they do, then it
is contended by Esso that the doctrine or
principle of restraint
of trade never has application to a restraint which is
imposed
upon the trading use to be made of a particular piece of land.
A review
of the authorities shows that in some groups of cases there has
been
no assertion that the doctrine or principle of trade applies. It is
said,
therefore, that there are classes of cases in which the
doctrine does not
apply, and attempt is made to define those
groups of cases in which alone
the doctrine does apply. For my
part, I doubt whether it is possible or
desirable to record any
very rigid classification of groups of cases. Nor do
I think that
any firm interference can be deduced from the circumstances that
in
respect of certain groups of cases no one has claimed that the
doctrine
applies or has sought to invoke it. That might be for the
reason that there
are some situations in which it would not be
thought by anyone that the
doctrine could successfully be invoked.
In some cases it matters not
whether it is said that the doctrine
does not apply or whether it is said that
a restraint would so
obviously pass the test of reasonableness that no one
would be
disposed even to seek to invoke the doctrine. I take the test to
be
as laid down by Lord Macnaghten in his speech in Nordenfelt
v. Maxim
Nordenfelt Guns and Ammunition Co. [1894] AC 535 at page 565 : -
" All
interference with the individual liberty of action in trading, and
"
all restraints of trade of themselves, if there is nothing more, are
con-
" trary to public policy, and therefore void. That is
the general rule.
" But there are exceptions: restraints of
trade and interference with
" individual liberty of action
may be justified by the special circum-
" stances of a
particular case. It is a sufficient justification, and indeed
"
it is the only justification, if the restriction is
reasonable—reasonable,
10
"
that is, in reference to the interests of the parties concerned and
"
reasonable in reference to the interests of the public, so framed and
so
" guarded as to afford adequate protection to the party in
whose favour
" it is imposed, while at the same time it is in
no way injurious to the
" public."
When
attempt is made to define what is meant by a contract in restraint
of
trade words are used which are of far-reaching application. Thus
Lord
Denning M.R., in the Petrofina case (Petrofina
(Great Britain) Ltd. v. Martin
[1966] 1 Ch. 140, 169) said: —
"
Every member of the community is entitled to carry on any trade
"
or business he chooses and in such manner as he thinks most
desirable
" in his own interests, so long as he does nothing
unlawful: with the
" consequence that any contract which
interferes with the free exercise
" of his trade or business,
by restricting him in the work he may do for
" others, or the
arrangements which he may make with others, is a con-
" tract
in restraint of trade. It is invalid unless it is reasonable as
"
between the parties and not injurious to the public interest."
So Diplock, L.J. in the same case (at page 180) said:-
" A
contract in restraint of trade is one in which a party (the
covenan-
" tor) agrees with any other party (the covenantee)
to restrict his liberty
" in the future to carry on trade
with other persons not parties to the
" contract in such
manner as he chooses."
These are
helpful expositions provided they are used rationally and not
too
literally. Thus, if A made a contract under which he willingly
agreed to
serve B on reasonable terms for a few years and to give
his whole working
time to B it would be surprising indeed if it
were sought to describe the
contract as being in restraint of
trade. In fact such a contract would very
likely be for the
advancement of trade. Yet Counsel for Harper's did not
shrink from
the assertion that every contract of persona! service is a
contract
in restraint of trade. I cannot think that either
authority or logic requires
acceptance of so extreme a view.
I approach
the present case by considering first whether the agreements
made
by Harper's should, in a reasonable sense, be regarded as in
restraint
of trade and, if they are to be so considered, secondly
the submission which
was made that, since the restriction can be
said to be a restriction of the
trading use to be made of a
particular piece of land, the doctrine of restraint
of trade has
no application.
The essence of the agreement of the 27th June, 1963, in reference to
Mustow Green Garage was that Harper's became tied to Esso. Harper's
agreed to buy from Esso their total requirements of motor fuels for resale
at Mustow Green Garage. They agreed also to operate the garage in
accordance with the Esso Dealer Co-operation Plan, one term of which was
" To keep the Service Station open at all reasonable hours for the use of
" Esso Motor fuels and Esso Motor Oils." I cannot accept the contention
that there was no positive obligation in regard to operating the garage but
only an agreement as to method of operation if the garage was in fact being
operated. In my view, Harper's agreed to operate the Garage in a particular
way and, above all, they agreed to take all their requirements of Motor Fuels
from Esso. Implied in this was an undertaking not to sell any other motor
fuels than those of Esso. The very basis of the agreement was restrictive.
It was designed to ensure that Harper's would not sell any of the motor fuels
that competed with Esso. It restricted the manner in which Harper's would
carry on their business. The supply agreement, dated the 5th July, 1962, in
reference to the Corner Garage had in general the same features.
If the
agreements are regarded, as I think that they must be, as being
prima
facie in restraint of trade then the question arises whether
there is
validity in the contention that the restriction was
merely of the trading use
to be made of a particular piece of land
and that, as a consequence, there
was exclusion of the
applicability of the doctrine of restraint of trade.
It was
powerfully argued that it has long been accented that a covenant in
a
lease of premises which prohibits the carrying-on of any trade or
business
upon the premises is not subjects to the tests of being
reasonable as between
11
parties
and not injurious to the public interest: and it was argued that
the
reason for this can be stated to be that the doctrine of
restraint of trade
applies to agreements which in substance
restrict the trade that a person
may engage in yet it does not
apply to agreements which in substance merely
restrict the use to
be made of a particular piece of land. It was said that
Harper's
covenants did not limit their activities anywhere else than
on
particular pieces of land, i.e., at their two Garages.
There is a
considerable difference between the covenants in the present
case
and covenants of the kind which might be entered into by a
purchaser
or by a lessee. If one who seeks to take a lease of land
knows that the only
lease which is available to him is a lease
with a restriction then he must
either take what is offered (on
the appropriate financial terms) or he must
(seek a lease
elsewhere. No feature of public policy requires that if he
freely
contracted he should be excused from honouring his contract. In
no
rational sense could it be said that if he took a lease with a
restriction as to
trading he was entering into a contract that
interfered with the free
exercise of his trade or his business or
with his " individual liberty of action
" in trading ".
His freedom to pursue his trade or earn his living is not
impaired
merely because there is some land belonging to someone else
upon
which he cannot enter for the purposes of his trade or business.
In
such a situation (i.e., that of voluntarily taking a lease of
land with a
restrictive covenant) it would not seem sensible to
regard the doctrine of
restraint of trade as having application.
There would be nothing which
could be described as interference
with individual liberty of action in trading.
There is a clear
difference between the case where someone fetters his
future by
parting with a freedom which he possesses and the case where
someone
seeks to claim a greater freedom than that which he possesses or
has
arranged to acquire. So, also, if someone seeks to buy a part of
the
land of a vendor and can only buy on the terms that he will
covenant with
the vendor not to put the land to some particular
use, there would seem in
principle to be no reason why the
contract should not be honoured.
The
agreements made by Harper's were quite different. Harper's had
their
garages. Esso had no interest in them or in the land on which
they
were situated. By the agreements, Harper's agreed for periods
of years to
limit and restrict their trading activity. They agreed
(in general) not to
sell any motor fuels other than those of Esso.
Prima facie the agreements
were in restraint of trade. They
were naked covenants or covenants in
gross. As covenants they seem
to me to have more of a personal character
than of a properly
character. They were concerned with the way in which
Harper's
would carry on their garages and their businesses. As Harman,
L.J.,
said in the Petrofina case, it is a person who trades and not
the land.
It is
agreed that no case has been cited which lays down or upholds
the
wide proposition that the doctrine of restraint of trade can
have no applica-
tion to a covenant which is merely restrictive of
the trading use to be made
of a particular piece of land. If such
a proposition were held to be sound
then, as Diplock L.J. pointed
out in the Petrofina case, there would be scope
to reframe
radius covenants in restraint of trade, even where the radius
was
very wide, as covenants not to carry on a particular trade in
a particular
manner on any premises in a defined area. Indeed, as
most activities and
enterprises take place in some way or other on
or in connection with land it
would be possible, if the
proposition were upheld, to frame a great many
covenants so as to
avoid their being open to the tests to which covenants in
restraint
of trade must submit. But, apart from this consideration, there
are
cases in the books which point to the novelty of the
proposition. Thus, in
English Hop Growers Ltd. v. Bering
[1928] 2 K.B. 174 the Defendant
undertook to deliver to the
Plaintiffs all the hops grown or produced by him
in a particular
year on land of a certain acreage. He contended that the
agreement
was not enforceable because it was in restraint of trade. The
Court
did not say that the contention could not be advanced. They did
not
say that as the Defendant's undertaking was restrictive of the
trading
use that he was making of his land the contention was not
open to him.
The Court considered the contention but held that the
undertaking of the
Defendant was not unreasonable: accordingly it
was enforced. In another
12
case,
Servais Bouchard v. The Princes Hall Restaurant (Limited)
20 T.L.R.
574 the Defendants agreed (for a consideration) to
give the Plaintiffs the
exclusive right of supplying certain wine
for the Defendants' restaurant. To
a claim made by the Plaintiffs
for a breach of the agreement one plea made
by the Defendants was
that the contract was void as being in restraint of
trade and
unlimited in time. The Master of the Rolls in his judgment said
that,
in his opinion, the case did not come within the principle by
which
contracts in restraint of trade were held to be invalid as
being contrary to
public policy. He thought that contracts such as
those by which persons
bound themselves to supply customers with
goods obtained from a particular
merchant exclusively were for the
benefit of the community. He pointed
out that contracts for sole
agency were matters of everyday occurrence. He
said that if the
contract was one of a kind which might be treated as
violating the
common law rule against contracts in restraint of trade
the
circumstances were such as to bring in the element of
reasonableness which
afforded an answer to the general rule.
Stirling L.J. in his judgment considered
and gave reasons for
rejecting the contention that the contract, being un-
limited in
point of time, was in restraint of trade. He did not suggest that,
as
the Defendants' agreement was restrictive of the trading use that
they
would make of their premises, their plea was not open to them
and could
not be considered.
In another
case. Foley v. Classique Coaches Ltd. [1934] 2 K.B. 1,
the
Plaintiff agreed to sell a piece of land (adjoining other land
belonging to
him) to the Defendants who proposed to use the land
for their business as
motor coach proprietors. The sale took
place. The sale was made
subject to the Defendants entering into
another agreement, which they did,
to buy from the Plaintiff (who
had a petrol-filling station on his adjoining
land) all the petrol
that they needed for the running of their business as
motor coach
proprietors so long as the Plaintiff was able to supply them.
In
proceedings by the Plaintiff to enforce this latter agreement
one contention
of the Defendants was that the agreement was an
unreasonable and un-
necessary restraint of the Defendants' trade
and was contrary to public policy
and illegal. It was held that
there was no " undue " restraint of trade. It
does not
appear to have been suggested that, as the Defendants' agreement
was
restrictive of the trading use that they would make of the land which
they
acquired, the doctrine of restraint of trade could not
possibly have applica-
tion or be raised for consideration.
For the
reasons which I have set out and subject to what I have said
above
I am unable to accept the contention in its wide form that in no
circum-
stances can the doctrine of restraint of trade apply to
contracts or covenants
regulating the trading use to be made of a
particular plot of land. The
agreements made in reference to the
two garages of Harper's were, in my
view, agreements in restraint
of trade. The question, therefore, arises whether
the agreements
can pass the tests of reasonableness. Esso allege that the
agreements
were reasonable as between the parties. The onus is on them
to
show that this is so. They must show that the restraint affords them
no
more than adequate protection for those interests which they
have a right
to have protected. In Herbert Morris v.
Saxelby [1916] 1 A.C. 688 Lord
Parker of Waddington at page
707 so stated the matter. In speaking of the
covenantor he added:
—
" As
long as the restraint to which he subjects himself is no wider than
"
is required for the adequate protection of the person in whose
favour
" it is created, it is in his interest to be able to
bind himself for the sake
" of the indirect advantages he may
obtain by so doing."
It becomes
necessary to consider separately the agreements in reference to
the
two respective garages. In doing so, however, the nature of
Esso's
legitimate interests qualifying for protection must be
remembered. There
was evidence that they had expended a large sum
of money in erecting
refineries. They spent money in the operation
of their Dealer Co-operative
Plan. Following their initiative in
introducing solus agreements other com-
panies followed suit with
the result that, at the time of the hearing before
the learned
Judge, out of 36,000 " outlets " in the United Kingdom at
which
13
a motorist
could buy motor fuels nearly 35,000 were subject to solus
agree-
ments. Of the 35,000 over 6,600 were with Esso. The
circumstance that
there are solus agreements in respect of so high
a proportion of garages
undoubtedly brings it about that delivery
charges are reduced. Overall
planning can effect further
economies. All these and kindred considerations
demonstrate that
it is essential for Esso to be able to plan ahead. In particu-
lar,
in order to ensure that they will be able to sell the motor fuel that
they
will produce for distribution it will be reasonable for them
to have secure
outlets. And as solus agreements became so much a
feature of the trade
and contained some features which were
advantageous to garage proprietors
it was reasonable for Harper's
to make arrangements in conformity with
current practice. This all
indicates, in my view, that from the point of view of
time alone
solus agreements which last for a few years are capable of
being
adjudged to be reasonable.
In the
case of the Mustow Green garage the duration of the solus
agreement
was four years and five months. Though that period was
arranged because it
was the unexpired period under a former
agreement which had been made in
reference to that garage I think
that the question to be decided is whether
the Appellants have
established that the tie as arranged for that period was
reasonable
as between the parties. When the agreement was made (in June.
1963),
price maintenance was in existence and Harper's agreed to abide
by
the retail schedule prices as fixed by Esso if they were so
fixed. Though at a
later date price maintenance no longer
continued it is pertinent to note that
under the agreement
Harper's were obliged to buy from Esso their total
requirements of
motor fuels for re-sale and to buy at Esso's wholesale
schedule
price. Harper's had a rebate from the price as fixed. Esso
could,
therefore, themselves fix their schedule price from time to
time. Also, there
was nothing to prevent them from selling
directly to some others (farmers
and traders) at a price less than
that which they fixed as their wholesale
schedule price. In
addition to being obligated only to buy from Esso,
Harper's agreed
to keep the filling station open (at all reasonable hours) and
agreed
only to sell or transfer to someone who would undertake the
obliga-
tions for any remaining period. Though in regard to the
price that Harpers
would have to pay Esso for their motor fuel
Harper's were in one sense at
the mercy of Esso, it is reasonable
to assume that Esso would wish to arrange
matters in such manner
as was best calculated to bring about a high volume
of trade in
Esso motor fuels. They would naturally have regard to the
prices
fixed by others and also to the circumstance that there existed a
certain
number of garages not bound by any ties. From a business
point of view
Harper's were not being unwise in entering into a
solus agreement of only
a few years' duration: but, whether they
were or not, they freely entered into
it and it was their decision
to repose a measure of confidence in Esso. I
considered,
therefore, that the real problem in the case of the Mustow
Green
contract is to decide whether for a contract of its nature a
duration of four
years and five months makes the contract
unreasonable as between the parties.
Though the evidence adduced
by Esso might have been more ample, and
probably would have been
had the litigation been initiated on the lines along
which it has
later developed. I consider that Esso did discharge the onus
of
showing that the contract was reasonable as between the
parties.
In the
case of the Corner garage the arrangements were very different.
There
was a solus agreement. There was also a loan agreement and a
mort-
gage. The solus agreement (dated the 5th July, 1962), was
for a period of
21 years. It was in similar terms to the solus
agreement relating to the
Mustow Green Garage. Esso lent a sum of
£7.000 to Harper's for the purpose
of helping Harper's to
buy the Corner Garage and to improve it and. by
the loan agreement
(dated the 12th July, 1962). Harper's agreed to purchase
all their
requirements of motor fuels from Esso until the loan and interest
had
been repaid. Furthermore, Harper's were to grant a mortgage to
Esso
as security for the loan. By the mortgage (dated the 6th
October. 1962).
Harper's were to pay off the loan (with interest)
over the period of 21 years.
Harper's could only redeem in
accordance with the agreement as to repay-
ment—with the
result that they could not redeem for 21 years. In the
mortgage
deed there was also a covenant by Harper's to occupy the garage
14
and to
conduct it and keep it open during normal business hours as
retailers
of motor fuels and there was a covenant to purchase
motor fuels exclusively
from Esso. There were various other
provisions of importance.
A
consideration of the facts and the documents leads me to the view
that
the solus agreement, the loan agreement and the mortgage can
be linked
together as incidents of one transaction and that the
intention was that in
providing that the mortgage should be
irredeemable for the period of the
tie it should become a support
for the solus agreement. It was the contention
of Esso that the
doctrine of restraint of trade does not apply to covenants
contained
in mortgages of land. As to this I will content myself
with
expressing agreement with the Court of Appeal, that the
doctrine of restraint
of trade does apply to mortgages. In regard
to the period of 21 years I con-
sider that Esso have failed to
show that a period of that length was reasonable
in the interests
of the parties. There was an unreasonable restraint of trade and
the
inclusion of it in the mortgage which was made irredeemable for
the
period went beyond what could be justified as a protection of
Esso's interest
to secure their loan. I agree with the Court of
Appeal that in the circum-
stances Esso should be entitled to
redeem.
In the
result I would allow the appeal in regard to the Mustow Green
Garage
and I would dismiss the appeal in regard to the Corner Garage.
Lord Hodson
MY LORDS,
This
appeal arises from two actions brought by the Esso Petroleum
Company,
Limited, against Harper's Garage (Stourport), Limited. The
Esso
Company had at first instance been granted injunctions against
the
Garage Company and the Garage Company's counterclaim for
certain
declarations had been dismissed, but the decision was
reversed on appeal
and the Esso Company now seek to restore the
judgment of the trial judge.
The
cases concern what have come to be known as " solus agreements
"
by which, in recent years, more and more garage stations in
this country
tied themselves to the big oil companies to buy all
their petrol therefrom,
to sell no other petrol and to sell at
prices fixed by the oil companies.
Your Lordships were informed
that at the present time of 36,000 stations
35,000 were so tied.
In
the cases now under consideration the tie imposed was in the one
case
(action 259) four years and five months' duration and in the
other (action
1249) of 21 years' duration. The first question is
whether or not the doctrine
of restraint of trade applies to these
solus agreements and, if so, does it apply
equally to a mortgage
which was entered into in the second case in connection
with the
solus agreement but not in the first case.
The
main contention on the part of the Appellants is
that these
agreements relate to the use of land and that the
doctrine of restraint
of trade has no application to a restriction
imposed on a piece of land
as opposed to a restriction imposed on
a person or corporation. Such
a restriction is exemplified in
contracts between master and servant, vendor
and purchaser of a
business and combinations to restrict output or fix prices
or the
like. This contention was accepted by the trial judge but has no
direct
authority to support it. It can be said that in many
scores of cases relating,
for example, to leases of land by
brewers to publicans and, in one case,
of a sale of the same sort
it has been taken for granted that such restrictive
covenants on
the use of land are and have been from time immemorial
imposed
without objection or criticism; therefore, the doctrine has
no
application. Thus the authorities may be said to support the
proposition
sub silentio, for no attempt has been made as a
rule to attack these covenants
on the ground that they are in
restraint of trade. An exception is to be
found in the case of
Catt v. Tourle (1869) L.R. 4 Ch., 654, where a
brewer
had sold a piece of land to the trustees of a freehold land
society who
covenanted with him that he, his heirs and
assigns should have the
exclusive right of supplying beer to
any public house erected on the land.
15
The
defendant, also a brewer, acquired a piece of land with notice of
the
covenant and erected thereon a public house which he supplied
with his
own beer. The covenant was held not an unreasonable
restraint of trade
although it was perpetual. Selwyn, L.J.
explained the reason in the following
words: —
" A
restraint preventing a person from carrying on trade within
"
a certain limit of space, though unlimited as to time, may be good,
"
and the limit of space may be according to the nature of the trade.
"
. . . We should be introducing very great uncertainty and con-
"
fusion into a very large and important trade if we were now to
"
suggest any doubt as to the validity of a covenant so extremely
"
common as this is. I think there is no ground for the distinction
"
which has been contended for, viz. that such a covenant might be
"
good in a lease for 21, 50 or 100 years, but is not good if entered
"
into as part of a transaction where the fee simple of a property is
"
conveyed."
It is to
be observed that, if the Appellants were right, the case could
have
been shortly disposed of by stating that the restriction
related to the sale of
a piece of land. Nevertheless, restraint of
trade was dealt with by the
court as if this simple answer was not
available. Several cases involving
indirectly, if not directly,
the use of land have been decided after considera-
tion of the
doctrine of restraint of trade as being applicable. Examples
are:
McEllistrim v. Ballymacelligott Co-operative Agriculture
and Dairy
Society Limited [1919] A.C. 548; English Hop
Growers Limited v. Dering
[1928] 2 K.B. 174 and Foley
v. Classique Coaches Limited [1934] 2 K.B. 1.
Apart
from authority, it would appear strange if the court, as it
admittedly
can, were to investigate the reasonableness of a
restraint of trade imposed
on an area or within a radius but were
to be precluded from investigating
one imposed on a particular
piece of land, for these two things are in
substance the same in
their effect in imposing a restraint of trade within
a prescribed
area.
One
learned writer alone, the late Mr. F. A. Gare, laid down
categorically
that restraints upon trade which arise upon a sale
of land are of a totally
different nature from those arising on a
sale of goodwill or a partnership
agreement. He added that these
restraints had never been treated by the
courts as in any way
dependent upon or governed by the same rule as
the other forms of
restraint of trade and, later, that there can be no
question of
public policy involved in such a covenant as that entered into by
a
purchaser restraining him from carrying on his trade on a piece of
ground
which he has newly acquired.
My Lords,
I do not think it is possible to accept this general proposition.
All
dealings with land are not in the same category ; the purchaser of
land
who promises not to deal with the land he buys in a
particular way is not
derogating from any right he has, but is
acquiring a new right by virtue of
his purchase. The same
consideration may apply to a lessee who accepts
restraints upon
his use of land ; on the other hand, if you subject yourself
to
restrictions as to the use to be made of your own land so that you
can no
longer do what you were doing before, you are restraining
trade and there
is no reason why the doctrine should not apply.
It is
difficult to devise a formula relating to land which covers all
cases
in which the doctrine should be excluded. Counsel for the
Respondents
submitted that the solution might be that the doctrine
only applied to
covenants for the benefit of the trade of the
covenantee which either forbids
the covenantor to carry on his
trade or restricts the manner in which he
does so. This solution
serves the property cases to which I have referred
where
restrictive covenants are given to protect property not trade but,
as
was pointed out in argument, does itself lead to anomalies in
practice as
between one property and another.
One
has to remember always what is meant by restraint of trade and
whence
this doctrine derives. It has been said to have its origin in
Magna
Carta, where words are to be found wide enough to extend to
freedom of
trade :
31739 A 8
16
"
Nullus liber homo etc. disseietur de libero tenemento vel
libertatibus.
" vel liberis
consuetudinibus suis etc."
These
words are quoted by Lord Macclesfield in Mitchel v. Reynolds
1 Peere
Williams (1711) 181 at page 188. He ended his judgment
by saying: —
" To
conclude: In all restraints of trade, where nothing more appears,
"
the law presumes them bad; but if the circumstances are set forth,
"
that presumption is excluded, and the Court is to judge of those
"
circumstances, and determine accordingly ; and if upon them it
appears
" to be a just and honest contract, it ought to be
maintained."
This
introduced the conception of reasonableness. Lord Macclesfield
had
already drawn the distinction between contracts made upon good
considera-
tion and those which were merely injurious and
oppressive.
Before
turning to reasonableness, however, I would adopt the language
of
Diplock, L.J. in the Petrofina case [1966] Ch. 146 at page 180
where he
said:
" A
contract in restraint of trade is one in which a party (the
"
covenantor) agrees with any other party (the covenantee) to
restrict
" his liberty in the future to carry on trade with
other parties not parties
" to the contract as he chooses."
The
learned Lord Justice was adapting his definition from the opinion
of
Lord Parker of Waddington in Attorney-General of the
Commonwealth of
Australia v. The Adelaide Steamship Co.
[1913] AC 781, 793. He
summarised the principle thus:--
" At
common law every member of the community is entitled to carry
"
on any trade or business he chooses and in such manner as he thinks
"
most desirable in his own interests, and ... no one can lawfully
"
interfere with another in the free exercise of his trade or
business
" unless there exist some just cause for such
interference."
When one
remembers that the basis of the doctrine of restraint of trade
is
the protection of the public interest, it is not difficult to see how
the law
developed in its conception of reasonableness as the test
which must be
passed in order to save a contract in restraint of
trade from unenforceability.
The law
has developed since the days of Mitchel v. Reynolds, and
many
disputatious matters have been cleared up. For example, as
Lord Mac-
naghten pointed out in Nordenfelt v. Maxim
Nordenfelt Guns and Ammuni-
tion Company [1894] AC 535 at
page 565, adequate consideration was
formerly thought to be
essential. He said:
" It
was laid down in Mitchel v. Reynolds that the Court was to
see
" that the restriction was made upon a good and adequate
considera-
" tion, so as to be a proper and useful contract.
But in lime it was found
" that the parties themselves were
better judges of that matter than the
" Court, and it was
held to be sufficient if there was legal consideration
" of
value, though of course the quantum of consideration may enter
"
into the question of the reasonableness of the contract."
Thus, a
restriction as to time may be reasonable or unreasonable according
as
to whether sufficient compensation has been given to the person
restrained.
The distinction between partial and general restraint
is no longer alive and
the courts are to-day left, I think, in the
position described by Lord
Macnaghten earlier on the same page,
where he said:
" The
true view at the present time, I think, is this: The public have
"
an interest in every person's carrying on his trade freely: so has
the
" individual. All interference with individual liberty of
action in trading,
" and all restraints of trade of
themselves, if there is nothing more, are
" contrary to
public policy, and therefore void. That is the general
"
rule. But there are exceptions: restraints of trade and
interference
" with individual liberty of action may be
justified by the special cir-
" cumstances of a particular
case. It is a sufficient justification, and
" indeed it is
the only justification, if the restriction is reasonable—
"
reasonable, that is, in reference to the interests of the parties
con-
" cerned and reasonable in reference to the interests of
the public, so
" framed and so guarded as to afford adequate
protection to the party
17
" in
whose favour it is imposed, while at the same time it is in no way
"
injurious to the public."
What Lord
Parker of Waddington said in the Adelaide Steamship Co.
case
follows naturally from this passage which puts into prominence
the
interests of the public. These are mentioned before those of
the individual.
True it is that the interests of the individual
are much discussed in the
cases on restraint of trade, which
seldom, if ever, have been expressly
decided on public grounds. An
interesting example of such a case is Kores
Manufacturing
Company Limited v. Kolak Manufacturing Company Limited
[1959]
1 Ch. 108 in which the discussion turned on whether or not
the
agreement in question was reasonable as between the parties
whereas it
could have been, perhaps, more readily based on the
public interest involved
in a commercial dispute. I should add
that it has been established that a
covenant against competition
per se will never be regarded as reasonable
(see the speech
of Lord Birkenhead L.C. in the McEllistrim case (supra)).
It has
been authoritatively said that the onus of establishing that
an
agreement is reasonable as between the parties is upon the
person who puts
forward the agreement while the onus of
establishing that it is contrary to
the public interest, being
reasonable between the parties, is on the person
so alleging: see
Herbert Morris Limited v. Saxelby [1916] A.C. 688, at
pages
700 and 707 and 708 per Lord Atkinson and Lord Parker. The
reason
for the distinction may be obscure, but it will seldom
arise since once the
agreement is before the court it is open to
the scrutiny of the court in all
its surrounding circumstances as
a question of law.
Having
rejected, as I do, the argument that there is a special class
of
contract relating to land which is outside the scope of the
doctrine of
restraint of trade, I come now to the question whether
the covenants in
question here are reasonable either in the
private interests of the contracting
parties or in the public
interest. There might be thought to be some risk
of proceedings
being taken in certain cases of a nuisance character where
the
restraint of trade is readily justifiable on the basis of long
established
practice in a particular sphere, such as the brewery
cases upon which the
Appellants rely, but I cannot see any
practical way of hedging about the
right of a party to a contract
to attack it on the ground that it has been
entered into in
unreasonable restraint of trade. After all, a man who freely
enters
into a bargain will, normally, expect to be held bound by it, and
I
do not anticipate a spate of litigation in which contracts of,
say, " sole
agency " will be assailed. In the case of
agreements between commercial
companies for regulating their trade
relations the parties are usually the
best judges of what is
reasonable. In such a case, as Lord Haldane said
in North
Western Salt Company Limited v. Electrolytic Alkali Company
Limited
[1914] AC 461 at 471, "the law still looks carefully to
the
" interests of the public, but it regards the parties as
the best judges of what
" is reasonable as between
themselves."
My Lords,
so far as the tie in the Mustow Green Garage is concerned,
I am in
agreement with the judgments given in the Court of Appeal, that
the
vital question is whether the length of the period for which the
agreement
is to last is unreasonable. There is a need for the
protection of continuity
of outlets for the company's petrol in
the area in which the station is. This
is a justification of the
tying covenant to which the compulsory trading and
the continuity
covenants are complementary, as Diplock, L.J. pointed out.
Without
them the tying covenant would be insufficient for its purpose.
They,
therefore, stand together. I should add that I reject the
argument of the
Appellants that the " keep open " clause
in the agreement falls short of a
compulsory trading clause.
I have,
however, reached the conclusion that the five-year tie is
not
unreasonable. It is true that there does not appear to have
been evidence
specifically directed to this question, but I have
been influenced by the
number of reported cases of like nature to
these, particularly from Common-
wealth courts, when five years
has been considered reasonable ; compare
also Biggs v.
Hoddinott [1898] 2 Ch 307, where a five-year tie was
con-
tained in a mortgage deed. The recommendation of the
Monopolies
18
Commission,
ordered to be printed on the 28th July, 1965, was that
solus
agreements should not normally exceed five years. Harman,
L.J. pointed
out that the period of four years and five months in
Action 259 was reached,
as it were, by accident without the
parties directing their minds to the
reasonableness of the period,
but I am not deterred by that feature of the
case from reaching
the conclusion that the period chosen, being less than
five years,
is not unreasonable. I would, therefore, reverse the order of
the
Court of Appeal so far as the Mustow Green Garage is concerned.
In the
Corner Garage there was not only a solus agreement but also
a
mortgage as security for a loan granted by the Appellants to the
Respon-
dents. The mortgage was irredeemable for 21 years and was
part and
parcel of the tying agreement and the compulsory trading
agreement, so
that unless ties contained in a mortgage are outside
the doctrine of restraint
of trade the period of 21 years is so
long as to be unreasonable in the
absence of evidence to justify
it. I see no reason why a tie in a mortgage
is to be treated in a
special way. The point was considered in Horwood v.
Millars
Timber & Trading Co. Ltd. [1917] 1 K.B. 305, although this
was
not a case of mortgage of land, and the court held that a
covenant in
restraint of trade contained in a mortgage deed was
bad. Reliance was
placed on Knightsbridge Estates Trust Ltd. v.
Bryne [1939] Ch. 441 and
page 457 for the proposition of
Sir Wilfred Greene, M.R., that " equity does
" not
reform mortgage transactions because they are unreasonable. It is
"
concerned to see ... that oppressive or unconscionable terms are
not
"enforced ". The Master of the Rolls was not dealing
with covenants in
restraint of trade. These must be tested by the
same criterion, whether they
are contained in mortgages or not,
unless there is some exception in relation
to land. I have already
expressed the view that there is no such exception.
I agree,
therefore, with the opinion of the Court of Appeal that the
tying
covenant and the compulsory trading covenant are
unenforceable. These
are so closely linked with the provision that
the mortgage is to be irredeem-
able for 21 years that I would
hold that they all fall together so that the
Respondents are
entitled to redeem. Finally, I should add that I do not
accept the
special argument based on section 85 of the Law of Property
Act,
1925, which is based on the conception that under the Act,
for conveyancing
purposes, a mortgage is treated as if it were a
lease.
I would
rest my decision on the public interest rather than on that of
the
parties, public interest being a surer foundation than the
interest of private
persons or corporations when widespread
commercial activities such as these
are concerned.
So far as
the Corner Garage is concerned I would affirm the order of the
Court
of Appeal.
Lord Pearce
MY LORDS,
On the
assumption that the solus agreement relating to the Mustow
Green
Garage comes within the ambit of the doctrine of restraint
of trade and that
its reasonableness is a matter which the Courts
must decide, I am of opinion
that it is reasonable.
The period
of five years has been approved as a reasonable period for
agree-
ments of this nature in Canada (British American Oil Co.
v. Hery, 1941
4 D.L.R. 725 ; McColl v. Avery,
1928 34 Ontario Weekly Notes 275 ; Great
Eastern Oil v.
Chafe [1956] 4 W.L.R. 2nd Series 310) and in South
Africa
(Shell Company of South Africa Ltd. v. Gerran's
Garages Ltd., 1954 4 S.A.R.
752). In the courts of this
country there is nothing which suggests that five
years is an
unreasonable length of time for a tie of this kind in a trade of
this
kind. In some cases the matter has passed subsilentio.
And although the
point was not relevant in Strick v.
Regent Oil ([1966] AC 295) the language
there used (per
Lord Reid at 324D and Lord Upjohn at 345E) seems to
suggest that,
had the question been raised or relevant, five years would not
19
have been
considered unreasonable. So, too, in the cases of Mobil
Oil
Australia, Ltd. v. Commissioner of Taxation of the
Commonwealth of
Australia ([1966] AC 275 at 293A) and B.P.
Australia Ltd. v. Commissioner
of Taxation of the
Commonwealth of Australia ([1966] A.C. 244 at 265C and
267E).
The facts set out in the report of the Monopolies Commission and
its
conclusions support this view.
Since the
war there has been a world-wide re-organisation of the
petrol
industry. The old haphazard distribution has, in the
interests of economy,
efficiency and finance been converted into a
distribution by the respective
petrol producers through their own
individual (and as a rule improved and
more efficient) outlets.
Vast sums have been spent on refineries, the improve-
ment of
garages and the like. Hand-to-mouth arrangements are no
longer
commercially suitable to the industry and considerable
planning (involving
inter alia the geographical spacing of
the outlets) is obviously necessary. The
garage proprietors were
not at any disadvantage in dealing with the various
competing
producers of petrol. To hold that five-year periods are too long
for
the ties between the producers and their outlets would, in my
opinion,
be out of accord with modern commercial needs, would
cause an embarrass-
ment to the trade and would not safeguard any
public or private interest that
needs protection. I would,
however, regard 21 years as being longer than was
reasonable in
the circumstances.
It is
important that the court, in weighing the question of
reasonableness,
should give full weight to commercial practices
and to the generality of con-
tracts made freely by parties
bargaining on equal terms. Undue interference,
though imposed on
the ground of promoting freedom of trade, may in the
result hamper
and restrict the honest trader and, on a wider view, injure
trade
more than it helps it. If a man wishes to tie himself for his
own
good commercial reasons to a particular supplier or customer
it may be no
kindness to him to subject his contract to the
arbitrary rule that the courts
will always reserve to him a right
to go back on his bargain if the court
thinks fit. For such a
reservation prevents the honest man from getting
full value for
the tie which he intends, in spite of any reservation imposed
by
the courts, to honour. And it may enable a less honest man to
keep
the fruits of a bargain from which he afterwards resiles. It
may be in this
respect similar to imposing on a trader the fetters
of infancy ; and many
an upstanding infant who wishes to trade or
buy a house or motorcar has
found difficulty and frustration in
the rule which the court has imposed for
his protection. Where
there are no circumstances of oppression, the court
should tread
warily in substituting its own views for those of current com-
merce
generally and the contracting parties in particular. For that
reason,
'I consider that the courts require on such a matter full
guidance from
evidence of all the surrounding circumstances and of
relevant commercial
practice. They must also have regard to the
consideration. It is clear
that the question of the consideration
weighed with Lord Macnaghten in
the Nordenfelt case [1894] AC 535 at 574). And although the court may
not be able to weigh
the details of the advantages and disadvantages with
great nicety
it must appreciate the consideration at least in its more
general
aspects. Without such guidance they cannot hope to arrive
at a sensible
and up-to-date conclusion on what is reasonable.
That is not to say that,
when it is clear that current contracts
(containing restraints), however wide-
spread, are in fact a
danger and disservice to the public and to traders,
the court
should hesitate to interfere.
The onus
is on the party asserting the contract to show the reasonable-
ness
of the restraint. That rule was laid down in the Nordenfelt case
(supra)
and in Herbert Morris Ltd. v. Saxelby
([1916] A.C. 688).
When
the court sees its way clearly, no
question of onus arises. In a
doubtful case where the court does not see
its way clearly
and the question of onus does arise, there may be a danger
in
preferring the guidance of a general rule, founded on grounds of
public
policy many generations ago, to the guidance given by free
and competent
parties contracting at arm's length in the
management of their own
affairs. Therefore, when free and
competent parties agree and the back-
ground provides some
commercial justification on both sides for their
20
bargain,
and there is no injury to the community, I think that the onus
should
be easily discharged. Public policy, like other unruly horses, is
apt
to change its stance; and public policy is the ultimate basis of the
courts'
reluctance to enforce restraints. Although the decided
cases are almost
invariably based on unreasonableness between the
parties, it is ultimately
on the ground of public policy
that the court will decline to enforce a
restraint as being
unreasonable between the parties. And a doctrine based
on the
general commercial good must always bear in mind the changing
face
of commerce. There is not, as some cases seem to suggest, a
separation
between what is reasonable on grounds of public policy
and what is reason-
able as between the parties. There is one
broad question: is it in the
interests of the community that this
restraint should, as between the parties,
be held to be reasonable
and enforceable?
The rule
relating to restraint of trade is bound to be a compromise, as
are
all rules imposed for freedom's sake. The law fetters traders
by a particu-
lar inability to limit their freedom of trade so
that it may protect the general
freedom of trade and the good of
the community. And, since the rule
must be a compromise, it is
difficult to define its limits on any logical basis.
The
court's right to interfere with contracts in restraint of trade (by
with-
holding its enforcement, which is the ultimate sanction of
contracts and
to which the parties are normally entitled) has been
put in very wide words.
Those words, though adequate and
appropriate to the particular cases in
which they were uttered,
were not directed towards an exact demarcation
of the line where
the court will have a right to investigate whether a bar-
gain is
reasonable and will decline to enforce it if it is not. The
famous
passages from the opinion of Lord Macnaghten in the
Nordenfelt case
(supra) and the opinion of Lord
Parker of Waddington in the Adelaide
Steamship Case [1913] AC 781 at 793 are not expressly limited in any
way. Since any
man who sells the whole, or even a substantial part, of his
services,
his output, his custom or his commercial loyalty to one party
is
thereby restraining himself from selling them to other persons,
it might
be argued that the court can investigate the
reasonableness of any such
contract and allow the contracting
party to resile subsequently from any
bargain which it considers
an unreasonable restraint upon his liberty of trade
with others.
But so wide a power of potential investigation would allow
to
would-be recalcitrants a wide field of chicanery and delaying
tactics
in the courts. Where, then, should one draw the line?
It seems
clear that covenants restraining the use of the land imposed as
a
condition of any sale or lease to the covenantor (or his successors)
should
not be unenforceable. It would be intolerable if, when a
man chooses
of his own free will to buy, or take a tenancy of,
land which is made subject
to a tie (doing so on terms more
favourable to himself owing to the existence
of the tie) he can
then repudiate the tie while retaining the benefit. I do
not
accept Mr. Templeman's argument that such transactions are subject
to
the doctrine, but will never as a matter of fact be held
unreasonable. In
my view, they are not subject to the doctrine at
all. Certainly public policy
gives little justification for their
subjection to it. This view would accord
with the brewers' cases
in which (after an earlier unfavourable protest by
Lord
Ellenborough, C.J. in Cooper v. Twibill 3 Camp. 286 at 287)
the
law has, for many years past, been firmly settled in allowing
covenants tying
the publican (as lessee or purchaser) to a
particular brewer (e.g. Clegg v.
Hands 44 C.D. 503).
In one case, however, in 1869 (Catt v. Tourle 4
Ch.
App. 654) a perpetual tie on a sale of land was subjected to
scrutiny and
was held to be reasonable. But to allow a permanent
tie is not very different
from holding it exempt from scrutiny.
It may be,
however, that when a man fetters with a restraint of land
which he
already owns or occupies, the fetter comes within the scrutiny of
the
court.
Is one
also to place mortgages in the class of cases from which the
doctrine
is excluded? Mr. Megarry for the Appellants relies inter
alia on the tech-
nical argument that under the mortgage he
has in law a demise of 3,000
21
years with
cesser on redemption; that this should not be regarded as a
mere
notional technicality; that he is a lessee for all purposes
(see Regent Oil
Co. Ltd. v. Gregory [1966] Ch. 402);
that the mortgagor is a lessor in pos-
session ; and that,
therefore, the covenant should bind him as on a lease,
But the
technicalities of the position where the mortgagor has no
subdemise
and is only notionally a lessor in possession put it on
the wrong side of the
line and the mortgagor cannot, therefore,
come into the class of lessees to
whose covenants the doctrine has
no application.
Then, on
broader grounds, does the mere fact that a restraint is embodied
as
an obligation under a mortgage exclude it from critical scrutiny
and
prevent its being unenforceable if it would have been so apart
from the
mortgage? I think not. In Biggs v. Hoddinott
[1898] 2 Ch 307 the point
was not raised and the case is,
therefore, of little guidance. The court of
equity which declines
to enforce the terms of a mortgage, if as a matter of
conscience
they are harsh and oppressive, cannot be less conscientious
with
regard to ties which as a matter of public policy the common
law courts
from earliest times, and thereafter courts of equity,
have consistently refused
to enforce in contracts. And the court
has rightly applied the doctrine
against restraint of trade to a
tyrannous mortgage of future earnings in
Norwood v. Millar's
Timber & Trading Co. Ltd. [1917] 1 K.B. 305.
But on the
question whether a restraint is reasonable, the fact that it
is
contained as a term in a mortgage may be a determining factor
in its
favour. The object of a mortgage is to provide fair
security for the lender.
And a restraint may be reasonably
necessary to protect the security when it
would not have been
reasonable without that object. Moreover, it seems
usually
reasonable for the tie to subsist as long as there is a loan
outstanding
which the borrower is unable or unwilling to repay. It
may be that even
so there must be a limit; but, if so, I would not
regard 21 years as necessarily
excessive since ex hypothesi
that length of time was commercially necessary
for the
borrower to have the benefit of the loan for his business. If,
there-
fore, there had been in the mortgage of the Corner House
Garage a right
to redeem either when the mortgagor wished or at
any time after a reason-
able term of years, say five or seven
years, and thereby to terminate the
tie I would not have regarded
the tie as unreasonable, in view of the amount
of the loan. But
here there was no such right to redeem. Nor did the tie
add
anything to the protection of the security. Here even in the
most
unlikely event of a shortage of petrol supplies the supplier
has a discretion
not to supply if his own sources of supply fail
or go short. And in any
other set of circumstances I cannot think
that a tied garage would be more
valuable than, or even as
valuable as, a free garage. Moreover, if the
mortgagees entered on
their security they would have to treat it as a free
garage and
account on that basis. If one regards the mortgage as a whole,
the
prolonged fetter on the right to redeem seems to have been
inserted
merely to prolong the tie. In this case, therefore, the
existence of the mort-
gage neither removes the tie from the area
to which the doctrine of restraint
of trade applies nor, in the
particular circumstances, does it assist the
Appellant on the
question whether the tie was reasonable.
Mocatta J.
in his clear and careful judgment held that neither tie was
in
restraint of trade since it was merely restrictive of the trading use
to be
made of a particular piece of land so that the doctrine of
restraint of trade
had no application. I feel the force of his
reasoning, but I do not feel
able to accede to it. Had the garage
proprietor had no obligations to carry
on his garage I might have
been persuaded otherwise. But here there was
a positive obligation
to carry on the business (or to find a transferee who
must do
likewise) and to purchase from none save Esso. The practical
effect
was to create a personal restraint. Although the covenant
affected only
petrol sold on the particular land it did affect the
proprietor with an obliga-
tion which he or his agents could not
by mere abstention avoid. Both the
English Hop Growers' case
([1928] 2 K.B. 174) and Foley & Classique
Coaches ([1934]
2 K.B. 1) in both of which the restraint was regarded as
reasonable
and McEllistrim's case, ([1919] A.C. 540) where it was not,
lend
some support to this view.
22
Finally,
there is the important question whether this was a mere agree-
ment
for the promotion of trade and not an agreement in restraint of it.
Somewhere
there must be a line between those contracts which are in
restraint
of trade and whose reasonableness can, therefore, be considered
by
the courts and those contracts which merely regulate the normal
commercial
relations between the parties and are, therefore, free
from the doctrine. The
present case seems near the borderline, as
was the case of Servais Bouchard v.
Prince's Hall
Restaurant 20 T.L.R. 574, where the learned Master of the
Rolls
held that the doctrine did not apply while the other two
Lords Justice
apparently held that it did apply but that the
restraint was reasonable.
One of the
mischiefs at which the doctrine was aimed originally was the
mischief
of monopolies. But this was dealt with by legislation and the
execu-
tive has from time to time taken efficient steps to prevent
it. Indeed, in the
case of petrol ties there has now been exacted
(we are told) from the petrol
producers an undertaking which in
practice limits these ties to five years.
When Lord
Macnaghten said in the Nordenfelt case (supra), at page
564
that " in the age of Queen Elizabeth all restraints of
trade whatever they
" were, general or partial, were thought
to be contrary to public policy and
" therefore void "
he was clearly not intending the words " restraints of trade
"
to cover any contract whose terms, by absorbing a man's
services or custom
or output, in fact prevented him from trading
with others; so, too, the wide
remarks of Lord Parker of
Waddington in the Adelaide case (supra) at page
794.
It was the sterilising of a man's capacity for work and not its
absorption
that underlay the objection to restraint of trade. This
is the rationale of
Young v. Timmins 148 E.R. 1446
where a brass foundry was during the
contract sterilised so that
it could only work for a party who might choose
not to absorb its
output at all but to go to other foundries, with the result
that
the foundry was completely at the mercy of the other party and
might
remain idle and unsupported.
The
doctrine does not apply to ordinary commercial contracts for
the
regulation and promotion of trade during the existence of the
contract, pro-
vided that any prevention of work outside the
contract viewed as a whole
is directed towards the absorption of
the parties' services and not their
sterilisation. Sole agencies
are a normal and necessary incident of commerce
and those who
desire the benefits of a sole agency must deny themselves
the
opportunities of other agencies. So, too, in the case of a
film-star who may
tie herself to a company in order to obtain from
them the benefits of stardom
(Gaumont British Picture
Corporation Ltd. v. Alexander [1936] 2 A.E.R.
1686).
See, too, Warner Brothers Pictures Incorporated v. Nelson
[1931] K.B.
209). And partners habitually fetter themselves to
one another.
When a
contract only ties the parties during the continuance of the
con-
tract, and the negative ties are only those which are
incidental and normal
to the positive commercial arrangements at
which the contract aims, even
though those ties exclude all
dealings with others, there is no restraint of
trade within the
meaning of the doctrine and no question of reasonableness
arises.
If, however, the contract ties the trading activities of either
party
after its determination, it is a restraint of trade, and the
question of reason-
ableness arises. So, too, if during the
contract one of the parties is too
unilaterally fettered so that
the contract loses its character of a contract for
the regulation
and promotion of trade and acquires the predominant character
of a
contract in restraint of trade. In that case the rationale of Young
v.
Timmins comes into play and the question whether it
is reasonable arises.
The
difficult question in this case, as in the case of Servais
Bouchard, is
whether a contract regulating commercial dealings
between the parties has
by its restraints exceeded the normal
negative ties incidental to a positive
commercial transaction and
has thus brought itself within the sphere to
which the doctrine of
restraint applies. If Esso had assured to the garage
proprietor a
supply of petrol at a reasonable price, come what may, in return
for
the garage proprietor selling only Esso petrol, it might be that the
con-
tract would have come within the normal incidents of a
commercial transac-
tion and not within the ambit of restraint of
trade. But Esso did not do this.
They hedged their liability
around so that they had an absolute discretion
23
in the
event inter alia of a failure in their own sources of supply,
whether or
not Esso should have foreseen it, to withhold supplies
from the garage pro-
prietor (leaving him the cheerless right in
such a situation to seek supplies
elsewhere); and then at a later
stage it would seem, if and when they were
prepared to supply him
once more, they could hold him to his tie with them.
And the price
was to be fixed by Esso. And for the duration of the contract
he
owed them a contractual obligation to continue to keep his garage
open
(or find a successor who would do so on like terms). When
these contracts
are viewed as a whole the balance tilts in favour
of regarding them as
contracts which are in restraint of trade and
which, therefore, can only be
enforced if the restraint is reasonable.
I do not here find help in the well known phrases that a man is not entitled,
to protect
himself against competition per se or that he is only entitled
to
protect himself if he has an interest to protect. It is clear
that a restraint
which merely damages a covenantor and confers no
benefit on a covenantee
is as a rule unreasonable. But here Esso
had a definite interest to protect
and secured a definite benefit.
They wished to preserve intact their spaced
network of outlets in
order that they could continue to sell their products
as planned
over a period of years in competition with the other producers.
To
prevent them from doing so would be an embarrassment of trade, not
a
protection of its freedom. If all the other companies owned
garages and Esso
were trying for the first time to enter the
market it would stifle trading com-
petition rather than encourage
it if Esso were prevented from being able to
enter into a binding
solus agreement for a so'e outlet in order to compete with
the
others. And in a doctrine based on the wide ground of public policy
the
wider aspects of commerce must always be considered as well as
the narrower
aspect of the contract as between the parties.
Since the
tie for a period of four years and five months was in the
circum-
stances reasonable, I would allow the appeal in respect of
the Mustow Green
garage. Since the tie for a period of 21 years
was not in the circumstances
reasonable, I would dismiss the
appeal in respect of the Corner Garage.
Lord Wilberforce
MY LORDS,
The main
features in the solus agreements entered into by the
Respondent
Company with Esso are that the Respondent agreed to
purchase from Esso
the whole of its requirements of motor fuel for
resale at the relevant service
stations, accepted a resale price
maintenance clause, agreed to operate the
relevant service
stations in accordance with the Esso Dealer co-operation
plan
which included a provision that the service station should be
kept
open at all reasonable hours for the sale of Esso petrol and
oil and, lastly,
agreed that, before completing any sale or
transfer of the relevant service
station, the Respondent would
notify Esso and procure the intended
successor to assume the
Respondent's obligations under the agreement.
In the
case of the Mustow Green Garage, the agreement, dated 27th
June,
1963, was expressed to operate for four years and five
months from 1st
July, 1963, this being the residue of a longer
period which was taken over
by the Respondent from a previous
operator of the station.
In the
case of the Corner Garage at Stourport-on-Severn the agreement,
dated
5th July, 1962, was expressed to operate for 21 years from 1st
July,
1962. In addition to this solus agreement, the Respondent
entered into a
mortgage of this station, dated 6th October, 1962,
by which the station
was charged to Esso to secure a sum not
exceeding £7,000 with interest.
The principal sum was
repayab'e—and only repayable—by instalments
over 21
years from 6th November, 1962. There were certain special
provisions
in the mortgage deed which I need not specify at the
present stage.
The first
main issue is whether these agreements are to be regarded
as
agreements in restraint of trade so as to be exposed to the
tests of reasonable-
ness stated in the Nordenfelt case. It
is the Appellant's contention that they
24
are not,
mainly on the ground that they relate to the use of the
Respondent's
land, and that covenants, or contracts, which so
relate are by their nature
incapable of being regarded as in
restraint of trade. This contention has
made it necessary to
consider how a covenant or contract in restraint of
trade is to be
defined or identified.
The
doctrine of restraint of trade (a convenient, if imprecise,
expression
which I continue to use) is one which has throughout
the history of its
subject-matter been expressed with considerable
generality, if not ambiguity.
The best known general formulations,
those of Lord Macnaghten in
Nordenfelt [1894] A.C. page 565
and of Lord Parker of Waddington in
Adelaide [1913] A.C.
793-7, adapted and used by Diplock L.J. in the Court
of Appeal in
the Petrofina case [1966] Ch. 146, 180, speak generally of
all
restraints of trade without any attempt at a definition. Often
we find the
words " restraint of trade " in a single
passage used indifferently to denote,
on the one hand, in a broad
popular sense, any contract which limits the
free exercise of
trade or business, and, on the other hand, as a term of art
covering
those contracts which are to be regarded as offending a rule
of
public policy. Often, in reported cases, we find that instead
of segregating
two questions (i) whether the contract is in
restraint of trade, (ii) whether,
if so, it is " reasonable
", the courts have fused the two by asking whether
the
contract is in " undue restraint of trade " or by a
compound finding
that it is not satisfied that this contract is
really in restraint of trade at all
but, if it is, it is
reasonable. A well-known text book describes contracts
in
restraint of trade as those which " unreasonably restrict"
the rights of a
person to carry on his trade or profession. There
is no need to regret these
tendencies: indeed, to do so, when
consideration of this subject has passed
through such notable
minds from Lord Macclesfield onwards, would indicate
a failure to
understand its nature. The common law has often (if
sometimes
unconsciously) thrived on ambiguity and it would be
mistaken, even if it
were possible, to try to crystallise the
rules of this, or any, aspect of public
policy into neat
propositions. The doctrine of restraint of trade is one to
be
applied to factual situations with a broad and flexible rule of
reason.
The use of
this expression justifies re-statement of its classic exposition
by
Chief Justice White in the Standard Oil Case (U.S. v.
Standard Oil (1911)
221 U.S.(1)). Speaking of the statutory
words "every contract in restraint of
"trade",
(Sherman Act 1890), admittedly taken from the common law,
almost
contemporaneous with Lord Macnaghten's formula and just as wide,
he
said:
" As
the acts which may come under the classes stated in the first
"
section and the restraint of trade to which that section applies are
not
" specifically enumerated or defined, it is obvious that
judgment must
" in every case be called into play in order to
determine whether a
" particular act is embraced within the
statutory classes, and whether
" if the act is within such
classes its nature or effect causes it to be a
" restraint of
trade within the intendment of the Act . . ." (ibid page 63).
And he
goes on to say that to hold to the contrary would involve
either
holding that the statute would be destructive of all right
to contract or agree
or combine in any respect whatsoever, or
that, the " light of reason " being
excluded,
enforcement of the statute was impossible because of its
Uncertainty.
The right course was to leave it to be determined by the
light of
reason whether any particular act or contract was within the
con-
templation of the statute. One still finds much enlightenment
in these words.
This does
not mean that the question whether a given agreement is in
restraint
of trade, in either sense of these words, is nothing more than
a
question of fact to be individually decided in each case. It is
not to be
supposed, or encouraged, that a bare allegation that a
contract limits a
trader's freedom of action exposes a party suing
on it to the burden of
justification. There will always be certain
general categories of contracts
as to which it can be said, with
some degree of certainty, that the " doctrine "
does or
does not apply to them. Positively, there are likely to be
certain
sensitive areas as to which the law will require in every
case the test of
reasonableness to be passed: such an area has
long been and still is that
25
of
contracts between employer and employee as regards the period
after
the employment has ceased. Negatively, and it is this that
concerns us here,
there will be types of contract as to which the
law should be prepared to
say with some confidence that they do
not enter into the field of restraint
of trade at all.
How, then,
can such contracts be defined or at least identified? No
exhaustive
test can be stated—probably no precise non-exhaustive test.
But
the development of the law does seem to show that judges have
been
able to dispense from the necessity of justification under a
public policy
test of reasonableness such contracts or provisions
of contracts as, under
contemporary conditions, may be found to
have passed into the accepted
and normal currency of commercial or
contractual or conveyancing relations.
That such contracts have
done so may be taken to show with at least strong
prima force
that, moulded under the pressures of negotiation, competition
and
public opinion, they have assumed a form which satisfies the test
of
public policy as understood by the courts at the time, or,
regarding the
matter from the point of view of the trade, that the
trade in question has
assumed such a form that for its health or
expansion it requires a degree
of regulation. Absolute exemption
for restriction or regulation is never
obtained: circumstances,
social or economic, may have altered, since they
obtained
acceptance, in such a way as to call for a fresh examination:
there
may be some exorbitance or special feature in the individual
contract
which takes it out of the accepted category: but the
court must be persuaded
of this before it calls upon the relevant
party to justify a contract of this kind.
Some such
limitation upon the meaning in legal practice of " restraints
"
of trade " must surely have been present to the minds of Lord
Macnaghten
and Lord Parker. They cannot have meant to say that any
contract which
in whatever way restricts a man's liberty to trade
was (either historically
under the Common Law, or at the time of
which they were speaking) prima
facie unenforceable and
must be shown to be reasonable. They must have
been well aware
that areas existed, and always had existed, in which
limitations
of this liberty were not only defensible, but were not seriously
open
to the charge of restraining trade. Their language, they would
surely
have said, must be interpreted in relation to commercial
practice and
common sense.
Any
attempt to trace historically the development of the common
law
attitude towards " restraints " of different kinds
would be out of place here,
and generalisations as to it are
hazardous. But a few examples of com-
paratively modern origin
show how some such rule of action, however
imperfectly I have
expressed it in words, has been operated. In some cases
the
process can be seen whereby a type of contract, initially regarded
with
suspicion, has later come to be accepted as not, or no
longer, calling for
justification.
First,
there are the brewery cases. Contractual clauses tying a
leased
public house to the lessor's beers have been known, and
commonly current,
at least since the early 19th century (for an
early case see Hartley v. Penall
(1792) Peake 178).
In the form which they then assumed (commonly
providing that if
the tying covenant was broken there should be an increased
rent
recoverable by distress) we find them encountering some judicial
criticism
(Cooper v. Twibill (1808) 3 Camp. 286 (n)
per Lord Ellenborough, C.J.).
But by 1850 they had become current;
the attrition of negotiation and
competition may be taken to have
worn them down to an acceptable shape
and in Can v. Tourle
(1859) L.R. 4 Ch. 654 the Court of Appeal in
Chancery not only
accepted that such covenants were outside the doctrine
of
restraint of trade, but were prepared to extend the exclusion to the
case
where the servient house was sold instead of leased. I quote
Selwyn, L.J.'s
words: —
"
With respect to this particular covenant, it seems to me that the
"
Court cannot but take judicial notice of its being extremely
common.
" Every Court of justice has had occasion to consider
these brewers'
" covenants, and must be taken to be cognisant
of the distinction between
" what are called free public
houses and brewers' public houses which
26
" are
subject to this very covenant. We should be introducing very
"
great uncertainty into a very large and important trade if we were
"
now to suggest any doubt as to the validity of a covenant as
extremely
" common as this is." (I.c. page 659) and
Giffard,
L.J. added " it does not go beyond the ordinary brewers'
covenant"
(ib. page 662). Neither of the Lords Justices, it
will be seen, puts his decision
upon the ground (simple and
decisive if he had thought it appropriate)
either that the
covenant related to the use to be made of land, or that it
was
imposed on a disposition of land. That it was too late to subject
such
tying covenants to the test appropriate in restraint of trade
was stated in
1889 by Bristowe, V.C. (Clegg v. Hands 44
Ch. D. 503), and the issue was
not even debated in the Court of
Appeal.
The
working of the same principle can be seen even earlier in relation
to
covenants restricting trade in leases generally. In the normal
exploitation
of property, covenants are entered into, by lessee or
lessor, not to trade at
all or not to carry on particular trades.
In 1614 (Rogers v. Parry 2 Bulst.
136) the issue,
whether a covenant in a lease for 21 years not to exercise
a
particular trade was in restraint of trade, was still
susceptible of debate, but
Coke C.J. and the judges of the King's
Bench upheld its validity. By 1689
this seems to have become
accepted doctrine, for in Thompson v. Harvey
(Comb.
121) Holt C.J. was able to say "it was usual to restrain a
lessee
" from such a trade in the house let" giving as
the reason " because I will
" choose whether to let or
not". (cf. in relation to chattels, United Shoe
Machinery
Co. of Canada v. Brunei [1909] AC 330, 343).
The same
has come to be true of dispositions of the freehold: for over
100
years it has been part of the normal technique of conveyancing to
impose
and to accept covenants restricting the use of land,
including the use for
trades or for trade generally, whether of
that conveyed or of that retained.
A modern example of this is
Newton Abbott Cooperative Society v. William-
son &
Tread gold Ltd. [1952] 2 Ch. 286.
One may
express the exemption of these transactions from the doctrine
of
restraint of trade in terms of saying that they merely take land out
of
commerce and do not fetter the liberty to trade of individuals;
but I think
one can only truly explain them by saying that they
have become part of the
accepted machinery of a type of
transaction which are generally found
acceptable and necessary, so
that instead of being regarded as restrictive
they are accepted as
part of the structure of a trading society. If in any
individual
case one finds a deviation from accepted standards, some
greater
restriction of an individual's right to " trade ",
or some artificial use of an
accepted legal technique, it is right
that this should be examined in the light
of public policy. An
example of this process in a lease (a lessor's covenant
as to
trading) may be found in Hinde v. Gray (1840) 1 M &
Gr. 195, and,
in a conveyance, in the Scottish case of Aberdeen
Varieties Ltd. v. Donald
[1939] S.C. 788.
Then there
is the well known type of case where a man sells his business
and
its goodwill and accepts a limitation on his right to compete. Here
too
we can see the period of scrutiny in the 17th century. That,
on the sale of
the goodwill of a business, a promise might validly
be given not to carry on
the relevant trade was established, after
debate, in Broad v. Jolliffe (1620)
Cro. Jac.
596—the covenant held void—reversed in the King's Bench 2
Roll.
Rep. 203, where Dodderidge J. said that it was the usual
course of men
in their old age to turn over their trade to
another; general recognition was
given to this type of covenant by
Lord Macclesfield in Mitchel v. Reynolds
(1711) 1.
P. Wms. 181, 191. So the rule has become accepted that, in
the
interest of trade itself, restrictions may be imposed on the
vendor of good-
will provided that they are fairly and properly
ancillary to the sale: if they
exceed this limit the "
doctrine " may be applied (see Leather Cloth Co. v.
Lorsont
(1869) L.R. 9 Eq. 345 where James V-C. excepted
"natural"
covenants from the "doctrine").
The line
of thought that restrictions may in some contexts be imposed,
and
upheld, where they have become part of the accepted pattern or
structure
of a trade, as encouraging or strengthening trade,
rather than as limiting
27
trade, is
I think behind the Courts' acceptance of exclusivity contracts
and
contracts of sole agency. So. in Servais Bouchard v.
Princes Hall Restaur-
ant Ltd. (1904) 20 T.L.R. 574, the
contract was for exclusive purchase of
burgundy for the
defendant's restaurant for an indefinite period. The
judgments of
the Lords Justices are based on different grounds and it was
held,
in any event, that the covenant was reasonable; but the judgment
of
Collins M.R. is instructive. He thought that the case did not
come within
the principle by which restraints of trade were held
to be invalid as being
contrary to public policy. Contracts of the
same class as that now in question
viz. contracts by which persons
bound themselves for good consideration to
supply their customers
with goods obtained from a particular merchant
exclusively, were
for the benefit of the community. There was need for
contracts of
this kind and the Court must have regard to the fact that con-
tracts
for sole agency were matters of every day occurrence (see too W.
T.
Lamb & Sons v. Goring Brick Co. Ltd [1932] 1
K.B. 710 where the agree-
ment was not challenged: British
Oxygen Co. v. Liquid Air Co. [1925] Ch.
383, 392: in
the Adelaide case an agreement for exclusive purchase of
a
more comprehensively restrictive character was held to be in
restraint of
trade [1913] AC 781, 806-8).
Lastly
(though this is still an uncertain field) certain contracts of
employ-
ment, with restrictions appropriate to their character,
against undertaking
other work during their currency may be
acceptable (cf. Warner Pictures Inc.
v. Nelson [1937]
1 K.B. 209; Gaumont British Picture Corporation v.
Alexander
[1936] 2 A.E.R. 1686). But here too if it is found that the
restric-
tion is purely limitative or sterilising, it may be
subject to examination (see
Gaumont British Picture Corporation
v. Alexander u.s. page 1692 per Porter J.
and compare
the facts in Young v. Timmins (1831) 1 Cr. & J.
331: the
decision was mainly based on inadequacy of
consideration).
These
illustrations are sufficient to show that the Courts are not
lacking
in tools which enable them to select from the whole range
of those contracts
which in one way or another limit freedom in
trading, segments of current
and recognisably normal contracts
which are not currently liable to be subjected to
the necessity of
justification by reasonableness. Such contracts may even
be
listed, provisionally, in categories (see Gare, The Law Relating
to
Covenants in Restraint of Trade (1935) ; Cheshire & Fifoot,
Law of Contract
6th Ed. (1964) pp. 324, 329 ff.) but the
classification must remain fluid and
the categories can never be
closed.
I turn now
to the agreements. In my opinion, on balance, they enter into
the
category of agreements in restraint of trade which require
justification.
They directly bear upon, and in some measure
restrain, the exercise of the
Respondent's trade, so the question
is whether they are to be treated as falling
within some category
excluded from the " doctrine " of restraint of trade.
The
broad test, or rather approach, which I have suggested, is capable
of
answering this. This is not a mere transaction in property, nor
a mere trans-
action between owners of property : it is
essentially a trade agreement between
traders. It is not a mere
agreement for exclusive purchase of a commodity,
though it
contains this element: if it were nothing more, there would be
a
strong case for treating it as a normal commercial agreement of
an accepted
type. But there are other restrictive elements. There
is the tie for a fixed
period with no provision for determination
by notice: a combination which
McEllistrim's case shows
should be considered together ([1919] A.C. 565):
and there is the
fetter on the terms on which the station may be sold.
Admittedly
Harpers could liberate themselves by finding a successor willing
to
take their place : admittedly, too, being a limited company, they
could
trade in several places simultaneously, so that even if they
remained tied
to these sites, and obliged to continue trading
there, they could in theory set
up business elsewhere. But just as
in McEllistrim's case (u.s.) the reality
of the
covenantor's restraint was considered more relevant than his
theoretical
liberty to depart, so here, in my opinion, addition of
all the ingredients takes
the case into the category of those
which require justification. Finally the
agreement is not of a
character which, by the pressure of negotiation and
competition,
has passed into acceptance or into a balance of interest between
28
the
parties or between the parties and their customers; the solus system
is
both too recent and too variable for this to be said.
The test,
suggested by the Appellants, seems, my comparison, artificial
and
unreal. The covenant, they say, is not in restraint of trade
because is relates
to the use of the Respondent's land. Not only
does it require an effort of
mind to regard the covenant in this
way, but the comment is obvious that
an opposite result would be
produced by a so slight an adjustment as by
relating the covenant
to an area of land instead of to a specific property.
The view
which I would take of the agreements, moreover agrees, as
that
suggested by the Appellants does not, with those reported
cases which have
been cited as bearing most directly upon the
present.
In
McEllistrim's case ([1919] A.C. page 548) this House decided
that the
obligation imposed on a farmer to sell all his milk to
the Respondent society,
a co-operative, was in restraint of trade
and unreasonable on the ground that
he was thereby prevented from
trading both in a wide area in Western
Ireland and (effectively)
elsewhere and that he had no means open to him to
withdraw from
the agreement. I find it impossible to extract from the case,
even
by an argument ex silentio, any inference that had the
Respondent's
obligations been limited to specified land of his,
the restrictions would have
been exempted from the doctrine. I
should be much more inclined to read
into it a willingness to
accept normal co-operative selling schemes and a
rejection of the
relevant rule because it was an unusual and excessive fetter
on
the farmer's personal liberty. English Hop Growers v. Dering
[1928]
1 K.B. 174 was another instance of co-operative
selling. It is one of those
cases to which I have referred in
which the decision was a compound one—
that the agreement
was not in unreasonable restraint of trade. It being
apparent that
the agreement was both of a normal type (according to
Romer, J.,
similar agreements were entered into by 95 per cent, of the
hop
growers) and Inter partes reasonable, it is natural
enough that the members
of the Court of Appeal based their
judgments in different degrees on both
these factors. Again one
may add that the case lends no support to the
Appellants'
suggestion that the decision was based on the personal character
of
the agreement or that it would have been any different, or
differently
expressed, had the agreement related more specifically
to the Respondent's
land. Then there is Servais Bouchard v.
Princes Hall Restaurant Ltd. (u.s.):
I have already
referred to this case; I need add here only that the
decision,
upholding the agreement, is not related in any way to
the fact that the
contract concerned the use to be made of land.
Lastly
there is Foley v. Classique Coaches [1934] 2 K.B. 1
where on a sale
of land the purchaser agreed to take all the
petrol he needed for his coaching
business from the vendor.
Scrutton, L.J. (page 11), with whom the other
Lords Justices
agreed, described the contract as an ordinary one to purchase
petrol
from a particular person and held there was no " undue restraint
of
" trade ", a compound finding, but the ordinary
commercial character of the
agreement was clearly a strand in it.
The fact that the agreement related
(as it plainly did) to the use
of the defendant's land played no part in the
decision.
On this
view of the agreements it becomes necessary to subject them to
the
test of reasonableness. As regards the two solus agreements, having
had
the benefit of reading the opinions which precede mine, I am
content to say
that I am in concurrence with them in the view that
the Mustow Green
agreement does, and that the Corner Garage
agreement does not (on account
of its long duration), satisfy the
test of reasonableness in the interests of the
parties. I would
only add two observations. The first relates to the ground,
I
think the main ground, on which the Court of Appeal held that even
the
4 years and 5 months for which the Mustow Green agreement was
to last
was too long. They were faced with the difficulty (which
faces us) that
there was very little evidence at the trial, and
because of the course the trial
took, no finding by the judge, of
facts which would support a tie for any
particular period. So the
Court of Appeal, which had to decide the question
of
reasonableness for the first time, devised a special and more
concrete
29
test of
their own. They asked themselves the question, how long it would
take
Esso to find an alternative site if the Respondent's site
were liberated from
the tie, and Lord Denning M.R. arrived at a
period of 3 years certain
and thereafter subject to 2 year's
notice. Diplock, L.J., while not committing
himself to any firm
period, thought that evidence might have justified a
period of 2
years or so, or an indefinite period subject to 2 years' notice.
I
do not feel able to accept this way of dealing with the matter. The
parties
have contracted in relation to a particular site and no
other: who can say
what features of it they considered relevant or
significant? How can one
judge what site, or whether any site,
would be an ' alternative' or to what
lengths Esso ought to go to
find one? What degree of continuity at one place
is Esso entitled
to expect, or, conversely, how often may Esso be expected
to move
its outlets without losing goodwill or profits? None of these
ques-
tions can, in my opinion, be answered with certainty and the
question to be
answered is a different question. For what the
Court is endeavouring to
ascertain is whether it is unreasonable
for Esso, in relation to Esso's interest
in selling petrol on this
location, to bind Harpers to it in the way that Harpers
is bound
for the period of the tie; or whether, in the public interest
of
preserving liberty of action to Harpers Ltd., they ought not to
be held in
the fetters which they have accepted. There appears to
me to be enough
in the evidence to show that, on Esso's side, to
secure a tie for this period
was a legitimate commercial objective
: and that as regards Harpers, no
public policy objection existed
against holding them so long bound. On this
point it is I think
legitimate to draw support from a number of decisions in
various
jurisdictions where restrictions of various kinds, over com-
parable
periods, have been upheld: (see British American Co. v.
Hery
(5 years) 1941 4 D.L.R. 725; Peters American Delicacy Co.
Ltd.
v. Patricia's Chocolates & Candies Property Ltd.
(3 years) 1947,
77 C.L.R. 574; Ampol Petroleum v.
Mutton (3 years) 1952, 53 S.R. N.S.W.
1 ; Shell (S.A.)
v. Gerrans Garage (5 years) 1954, 3 S.A.R. 752 ; Great
Eastern
Oil Co. v. Chafe (5 years) 1956 4 D.L.R. 310). I
should add that I must not
be taken either as suggesting that the
periods mentioned are maximum
periods, or as expressing any
opinion as to the validity of ties for periods
intermediate
between 5 years and 21 years such as, for example, existed in
the
Petrofina case (12 years) (1966) Ch. 146.
The second
observation I would make is this: the case has been
fought
exclusively on the first limb of the Nordenfelt test
of reasonableness (in
reference to the interests of the parties)
the Respondent explicitly disclaiming
any reliance on the second
limb (in reference to the interests of the public).
The first limb
itself rests on considerations of public policy: it must do so
in
order to justify releasing the parties from obligations they
have voluntarily
accepted. But in relation to many agreements
containing restrictions, there
may well be wider issues affecting
the interests of the public, than those which
relate merely lo the
interests of the parties ; these may have been the subject
of
enquiry as in this case under statutory powers (Monopolies and
Restrictive
Practices (Inquiry and Control) Act, 1948) or the
subject of a finding by
another Court (Restrictive Trade Practices
Act, 1956) or may be investigated
by the Court itself. In the
present case no separate considerations in this
wider field have
emerged which are inconsistent with the validity of the
Mustow
Green solus agreement—on the contrary such as have appeared
tend
to support it, but I venture to think it important that the
vitality of the second
limb, or as I would prefer to put it of the
wider aspects of a single public
policy rule, should continue to
be recognised.
Finally it
is necessary to deal separately with the mortgage on the
Res-
pondent's Corner Garage, which the Appellant contends falls
in a separate
category, not subject to the ' doctrine ' of
restraint of trade at all. The
submission is that, under accepted
principles of equity, there is nothing to
prevent a mortgage being
made irredeemable for a period provided (and
this is the only
suggested limitation) that the terms of it are not harsh
or
unconscionable: for this the Appellant invokes the well known
judgment
of Lord Greene M.R. in Knightsbridge Estates Trust
Ltd. v. Byrne [1939]
Ch. 441. Indeed the Appellant's
position is even stronger, it is claimed
30
because
the mortgage ranks as a debenture (ibid. [1940] A.C. 613) and so
may
legitimately be made completely irredeemable (Companies Act,
1948
sections 89, 455 (1) s.v. debenture). The steps in this
argument are coherent
once its foundation is made good—that
mortgages as such and restrictions in
them fall totally outside
the ' doctrine' of restraint of trade. But is this
foundation
sound? I consider first the relevant authorities.
The best
known of these is Biggs v. Hoddinott [1898] 2 Ch 307, a
brewery mortgage case. The decision is conveniently
summarised by Lord
Davey thus: first that a stipulation for the
continuance of a loan for five
years was valid, and secondly, that
a covenant to take beer from the mort-
gagee limited to the
continuance of the security did not clog the equity of
redemption
(see Bradley v. Carritt [1903] AC 253, 267). The issue as
to
restraint of trade was not raised. In Morgan v.
Jeffreys [1910] 1 Ch 620
another brewery case, where the
contractual right of redemption had passed, a
provision against
redemption before the expiry of 28 years, coupled with a
tie, was
held to exceed all reasonable limit, but again no question of
restraint
of trade was raised. Biggs v. Hoddinott was
recently followed by Russell
J. in Hill v. Regent Oil
(reported in Estates Gazette Digest 1962 page 452)
where there
was a mortgage, coupled with a tie, for 20 years and it was held
that
this was not oppressive or unconscionable. The case again was
decided
purely on the classical principles of equity applicable to
mortgages and the
judgment makes no reference to restraint of
trade. A similar decision was
given in Ontario in Clark v.
Supertest Petroleum Corp. (1958) 14 D.L.R. 2.
454. These
authorities then establish, and to that extent I have no desire
to
question them, that as part of a transaction of mortgage, it is
permissible, so
far as the rules of equity are concerned, both to
postpone the date of repay-
ment and. at any rate during the
period of the loan, to tie the mortgagor
to purchase exclusively
the products of the mortgagee. Such an arrangement
would fall
fairly within the principle I have earlier suggested, as
coming
within a recognised and accepted category of transactions,
in precisely the
same manner as a lease. But just as provisions
contained in a lease, affecting
the lessees' (or lessors') liberty
of trade, which pass beyond what is normally
found in and
ancillary to this type of transaction and enter upon the field
of
regulation of the parties' trading activities may fall to
be tested as possible
restraints of trade, so, in my opinion,
may those in a mortgage. The mere
designation of a transaction
as a mortgage, however true, does not ipso facto
protect
the entire contents of the arrangements from examination,
however
fettering of trade these arrangements may be. If their
purpose and nature
is found not to be ancillary to the lending of
money upon security, as, for
example, to make the lending more
profitable or safer, but some quite
independent purpose, they
may and should be independently scrutinised. This
scrutiny is
called for in the present case: for it is clear, upon
consideration
of the mortgage both taken by itself and in its
relation to the solus agreement
which shortly preceded it, that
so far from the tie being ancillary to a
predominant transaction
of lending money, the mortgage, as was the solus
agreement, was
entered into as part of a plan, designed by Esso, to tie
the
Corner Garage to its products for as long as possible. As Harman,
L. J.,
put it, after a detailed examination of the terms of the
mortgage which I
forbear from repeating, " the mortgage was
intended to bolster up the solus
" agreement". It
follows, in my opinion, that it must be judged by the test
of
reasonableness. If this is so, I think there can be little doubt,
once
a conclusion adverse to the restrictions is reached as to the
solus agreement
affecting the Corner Garage, that the same must
follow as regards the mort-
gage. I should add that the
Appellant added to his main argument on
this point a subsidiary
contention that the stipulations in the mortgage
should be
regarded in the same legal light as if they had been contained in
a
lease. For this he referred to section 85 of the Law of Property
Act 1925
and Regent Oil Co. v. Gregory [1966] Ch.
402. I cannot accept this esoteric
argument. For if it be the
case that inclusion of the relevant restrictions in
a mortgage
does not save them from examination, they surely cannot be
saved
because, for conveyancing purposes, the mortgage also bears
the character of
a lease. The relationship between the covenant
and a lease of the garage
site is too technical and notional to
bring the case within the recognised
31
exemption
which, within limits which I have earlier stated, applies to
actual
leases of an accepted character.
In my
opinion the appeal should be allowed as regards the Mustow
Green
garage and the judgment and order of Mocatta J. so far restored.
As
regards the Corner Garage it should be dismissed.
(31739) Dd. 196965 150 2/67 PA19/St.S.