BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £5, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
United Kingdom Upper Tribunal (Lands Chamber) |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> United Kingdom Upper Tribunal (Lands Chamber) >> Culley v Daejan Properties Ltd [2009] UKUT 168 (LC) (07 September 2009) URL: http://www.bailii.org/uk/cases/UKUT/LC/2009/LRA_63_2007.html Cite as: [2010] L & TR 2, [2009] UKUT 168 (LC) |
[New search] [Printable PDF version] [Help]
|
||
UPPER TRIBUNAL (LANDS CHAMBER) |
||
|
||
UT Neutral citation number:
[2009] UKUT 168 (LC) LT case number: LRA/163/2007
TRIBUNALS, COURTS AND ENFORCEMENT ACT 2007
LEASEHOLD ENFRANCHISEMENT –
deferment rate – hope value – collective enfranchisement – 1930s flats in
outer London – deferment rate 5% affirmed – hope value of flats of
non-participating tenants taken at 10% of marriage value – Leasehold
Reform, Housing and Urban Development Act 1993, Sch
11 |
||
|
||
IN THE MATTER of AN APPEAL
FROM THE LEASEHOLD VALUATION TRIBUNAL of the RESIDENTIAL PROPERTY TRIBUNAL
SERVICE |
||
|
||
BETWEEN
AMANDA JANE CULLEY
Claimant
and DAEJAN PROPERTIES LIMITED Respondent Re: 5 – 8 Royston Court, North
View, Eastcote, Middx HA5 1PG Before: The President and P R Francis
FRICS |
||
|
||
Sitting at Procession House,
110 New Bridge Street, London EC4V 6JL
on 23 March
2009 |
||
|
||
Stan Gallagher instructed
by Gisby Harrison, of Cheshunt, Herts, for the appellant Anthony
Radevsky instructed by Wallace LLP for the
respondent |
||
|
||
© CROWN COPYRIGHT 2009
1 |
||
|
||
|
||
The following cases are referred to in this
decision:
Cadogan v Sportelli [2006] RVR 382 (LT); [2008] 2 All ER 220 (CA); [2009] 2 WLR 12 (HL)
Hildron Finance Ltd v
Greenhill Hampstead Ltd [2008] EGLR 179
Daejan Investments Ltd v The
Holt (Freehold) Ltd LRA/113/2006, 2 May 2008
Haresign v St John’s College,
Oxford (1980) 255 EG 711
Farr v Millersons Investments
Ltd (1971) 22 P & CR 1055
Windsor Life Assurance Co Ltd
v Austin [1996] 2 EGLR 169
Marlodge (Monnow) Ltd’s Appeal
(LRA/28/2002)
Nicholson’s Appeal
LRA/29/2006, 8 January 2007
Eyre Estate (Trustees’) Appeal
LRA/145/2006, 16 February 2006
Ulterra Ltd v Glenbarr (RTE)
Company Ltd LRA/149/2006, 17 November 2007
Daejan Investments Ltd v The
Holt (Freehold) Ltd LRA/133/2006, 2 May 2008
Lippe Cik v Chavda
LRA/111/2007, 7 August 2008
Becker Properties v Garden
Court NW8 Property Company Limited [1998] 1 EGLR 121
Maryland Estates v Campana
Court Limited LRA/21/2000, 10 April 2001
Shulem B Association Limited’s
Appeal [2001 1 EGLR 105
Blendcrown Limited v The
Church Commissioners for England [2004] 1 EGLR 143
Tyndale & Others v
Kingsgarn Limited LRA/1/2002, 17 July 2002
Arbib v Earl Cadogan
[2005] 3 EGLR 139
Gesso Properties (BVI) Ltd v
SCMLLA Ltd LRA/13/2003, 1 March 2004 |
||
|
||
2 |
||
|
||
|
||
DECISION |
||
|
||
Introduction |
||
|
||
1. This is an appeal from a
decision of the Leasehold Valuation Tribunal for the London Rent
Assessment Panel, determining the price to be paid under Schedule 6 to the
Leasehold Reform, Housing and Urban Development Act 1993 on an application
made by Amanda Jane Culley as nominee purchaser, in respect of 5–8 Royston
Court, North View, Eastcote, Middlesex, on 8 February 2006. The LVT
determined the price to be paid for the freehold of the four flats in the
sum of £40,283 and in doing so applied a deferment rate at
5.0%. |
||
|
||
2. The LVT decision was given
after the Lands Tribunal had given it decision in Cadogan v Sportelli
[2006] RVR 382 but before the Court of Appeal’s decision on appeal
[2008] 2 All ER 220. On 5 February 2008, the President granted permission
to appeal, limited to the deferment rate issue only. In it he
said:
“The LVT reluctantly concluded
that it was obliged to follow the guidelines in Sportelli and to
apply a deferment rate of 5%, in the absence of any compelling evidence or
particular features which suggested that the disadvantages of the location
and of the property were not taken into account in the capital values. In
the light of the Court of Appeal judgment in Sportelli, the proper
test is somewhat less strict, namely whether there is sufficient evidence,
for example on issues relevant to the risk premium for residential
property in different areas, to justify a departure from the 5% starting
point. Although some (but not all) of the arguments put forward by the
applicant’s expert at the LVT were rejected by this Tribunal in Hildron
Finance Ltd v Greenhill Hampstead Ltd (LRA/120/2006), and are unlikely
to be accepted if raised again before the Lands Tribunal, it is considered
that the proposed appeal is of potentially wide importance and should be
considered by the Lands Tribunal.” |
||
|
||
3. After this limited permission
had been granted the House of Lords gave its decision in Sportelli
(Earl Cadogan v Sportelli [2009] 2 WLR 12). The decision was
confined to the issue of hope value. The LVT in the present case,
following Sportelli in the Lands Tribunal, made no allowance for
hope value. The House of Lords (Lord Hoffman dissenting) determined that
hope value could constitute part of the price payable to the freeholder in
relation to non-participating flats on a collective enfranchisement. In
the light of this, permission to appeal on the question of hope value was
given, and the experts subsequently produced supplemental reports covering
this matter. |
||
|
||
4. Mr Stan Gallagher of counsel
appeared for the appellant and called Mr Bruce Roderick Maunder-Taylor
FRICS MAE. Mr Anthony Radevsky appeared for the respondent freeholder, and
called Mr Eric Frank Shapiro BSc (Est Man) FRICS IRRV FCIArb. Following
the hearing we requested and later received further evidence and
submissions that we refer to below, and we received a final revised
valuation shortly before finalising this decision. |
||
|
||
3 |
||
|
||
|
||
5. The property is situated in
the 1930s suburb of Eastcote in the London Borough of Hillingdon. It is a
detached purpose built two-storey block of four bay-fronted flats
constructed in the 1930s of part rendered brick under conventional pitched
and tiled roofs, each flat having its own entrance from a recessed porch
off the front garden. Flats 5 and 8 are ground floor units each having two
rooms, and kitchen with bathroom/wc off. They each have a gross internal
floor area of 471 sq ft. Flats 6 and 7 are on the first floor, contain
three rooms, kitchen and bathroom/wc and have a gross internal area of 555
sq ft. The first floor flats have small rear balconies and steel
staircases leading down to the rear garden. Each unit has its own
allocated strip of the rear garden. The rearmost boundaries back onto a
station car park beyond which lies an above ground section of the London
Underground, and Eastcote station is very close by. Ms Culley is the
lessee of flat 7 and the lessees of flats 5 & 6 are not
participating. |
||
|
||
6. The lease of each of the flats
is for a term of 99 years from 24 June 1972, and had 65.37 years unexpired
at the agreed valuation date of 8 February 2006. The ground rents are as
follows:
Flat 5 £25/£50/£75 per annum
rising every 33 years
Flat 6 £25 per annum without
review
Flats 7 & 8 £20/£35/£50 per
annum rising every 33 years
The parties agreed the LVT’s
determination of the capitalised rental values of flats 7 and 8 at £1,030
each, and flats 5 and 6 at £1,095 each. They also agreed the capitalised
values thus:
Freehold/long leasehold values of
flats 6 & 8
£145,000
Freehold/long leasehold values of
flats 5 & 7
£160,000
Existing lease value of
participating flat 8
£126,150
Existing lease value of
participating flat 7
£139,200 |
||
|
||
Deferment rate |
||
|
||
7. Before the LVT Mr Maunder
Taylor contended for a deferment rate of 8%. He expressed his disagreement
with the Tribunal’s decision in Sportelli, which, he said, had not
had sufficient regard to obsolescence in the true sense of the word and to
locational differences. He considered that the subject property, because
of its layout and other factors, had a greater degree of obsolescence than
the properties considered in Sportelli and that the decision was
distinguishable because no allowance had been made for the risks at the
termination of the leases in the absence of hope
value. |
||
|
||
8. On the question of deferment rate, the LVT
said:
“9. We consider that we are
obliged to follow the guidelines in Sportelli and to apply a
deferment rate of 5%, there being no compelling evidence or particular
features which suggest that the disadvantages of the location and of the
property are not taken into account in capital values. We do have
misgivings as, we think, do most property valuers, about a ‘one size fits
all’ deferment rate, and, had it not been for |
||
|
||
4 |
||
|
||
|
||
Sportelli, we have little
doubt that we would have determined a deferment rate of 7% or thereabouts:
certainly no lower than 7%, and possibly higher if hope value is to be
disregarded altogether as Sportelli says it must be. Our misgivings
arise from our doubts whether the risks to an investor associated with an
investment of this type, in a suburban location and with potential
management problems associated with unsatisfactory leases, really do
justify the same risk rate as high value properties on one of the great
estates in Central London. A relatively small difference in the deferment
rate can have a very large effect on the price, and, to illustrate this,
we have prepared a hypothetical valuation on the basis of a deferment rate
of 7% and attached it to this decision at appendix 2 [£26,925].
Nonetheless, we accept the Lands Tribunal is entitled to issue guidelines,
that it is not for us to say that Sportelli was wrongly decided,
and that the guidelines must be followed.” |
||
|
||
9. One of Mr Maunder Taylor’s
contentions before the LVT was that, if hope value was to be excluded as a
matter of law, the willing buyer, obliged to wait to the end of the term
to realise his investment, would expect to receive a building that was
unmodernised and, with property such as that in the present case, he would
be likely to assume that the value of the property lay in it as a site
rather than in the building. The LVT rejected this argument “on balance”.
It said:
“We accept that an investor will
assume that the building will be standing and will be in good repair at
the end of the leases, and he will not reduce his bid to take account of
perceived risks at termination, which, he will assume, he can take in his
stride.” |
||
|
||
10. Before us Mr Maunder Taylor
said that in his opinion the Sportelli rate of 5%, if applied to
non-prime properties and in non-prime locations, often produced a
valuation result substantially different from a competent valuation which
disregarded the Sportelli rate. That was his view, and to give
evidence that applied any rate other than the one he considered to be
appropriate would be contrary to his duty as an expert. He had given
evidence before the Lands Tribunal in Hildron Finance Ltd v Greenhill
Hampstead Ltd [2008] EGLR 179 and had supported a deferment rate of 8%
on a collective enfranchisement on a block of flats in Hampstead. He there
expressed his disagreement with the Tribunal’s decision in
Sportelli. The Tribunal (Judge Reid QC and N J Rose FRICS) applied
a rate of 5%. Mr Maunder Taylor said that he considered that that decision
was wrong and that a deferment rate applicable to prime properties in the
best parts of central London was inappropriate both to Greenhill and to
Royston Court. He said that he had also advised the nominee purchaser on
the collective enfranchisement of The Holt, Morden, that led to the
decision of the Tribunal in The Holt (Daejan Investments Ltd v
The Holt (Freehold) Ltd LRA/113/2006, 2 May 2008) (Judge Huskinson and
A J Trott FRICS) applying the 5% deferment rate. He said that he had no
particular evidence or opinions that would distinguish that case from the
present one. He accepted that the evidence that he was now giving was the
same as that which he had given in The Holt and had been rejected
by the Tribunal in its decision in that case. |
||
|
||
11. Support for his view that the
Sportelli 5% should not be applied as a universal rate, Mr Maunder
Taylor said, came from a number of sources. Firstly he had carried out a
survey of valuers, writing to as many valuers as he could locate who were
experienced in Leasehold Reform Act valuations. Only a few of the replies
expressed agreement with the universal |
||
|
||
5 |
||
|
||
|
||
application of the Sportelli
rate. In cross-examination he said that he had sent out between 100
and 200 letters, but he did not know how many, and had received about 30
replies. Further, while the great majority of LVT decisions adopted the
Sportelli rate, Mr Maunder Taylor said, a number did not, and he
relied on this. He also derived support from an article by Professor
Farrand, an LVT chairman, in Bulletin 44 of Emmet and Farrand on
Title. |
||
|
||
12. On four occasions, Mr Maunder
Taylor said, he had given evidence for landlords before LVTs applying a
Sportelli deferment rate. In 8 Wetherby Place, London SW7, where
the deferment rate was in issue, he had been instructed that the landlord
would argue for a Sportelli 4.75%, but he drew the LVT’s attention
to evidence that he had previously given in a similar quality location at
a higher deferment rate. In 86 Gladesmore Road, London N15, he acted as
advocate for the landlord. The deferment rate was in issue. He gave no
expert evidence on this issue, and submitted to the LVT that the
Sportelli rate should be adopted in its decision. In 7 Brechin
Place, London SW7, he gave expert evidence for the landlord. The deferment
rate was in issue. He was instructed to apply the Sportelli rate,
so that this did not form part of his expert evidence. In 6 Parkside,
Knightsbridge, London SW7, a prime PCL property, he acted for the landlord
in the dual role of advocate and expert witness. The deferment rate was
not in issue. |
||
|
||
13. Mr Maunder Taylor said that
he had considered the question of the deferment rate in relation to
comparative long-term growth rates. He was aware of an analysis that Mr
Shapiro had prepared and presented to LVTs showing comparative growth
rates in London on a borough by borough basis covering the period April
2000 to September 2007. The four boroughs that were considered to include
the prime areas were not top of the percentage increases. That did not
surprise him. Those were the areas in which it was expected that there
would be steady growth. He would expect the list to be topped by those
sub-prime areas that for one reason or another were seeing unusual price
growth. It was unlikely that the level of growth would be sustained over
the long term, so that, when the reasons for that price growth changed,
such locations were likely to fall significantly further down the list. At
the bottom of the list he would expect to see modest value locations for
which there was no unusual reason for them to be experiencing any
particular upside on a volatility cycle. |
||
|
||
14. Investors reacted to this
market behaviour, Mr Maunder Taylor said, in different ways. Firstly there
were those investors who wanted least risk but best steady returns. They
wanted to invest in prime areas and for that they were willing to buy
their investment at a price reflecting a low yield or deferment rate.
Secondly there were those investors who were looking for higher returns
and were prepared to make speculative investments. They endeavoured to
identify those locations which were likely to show strong growth over
future years for reasons not yet recognised by the market at large. They
would pay a price that reflected both the speculative chance that they
were right as well as the speculative risk that they might be wrong. The
yield or deferment rate was likely to be higher than for prime areas but
not as high as those areas in which they perceived that there was no
chance of unusual future improvement. Thirdly there were those investors
who were always looking for the highest yield or deferment rate and who
accepted that, in order to achieve it, they must invest in non-prime
properties with no particular reason why their slower growth rate should
change. |
||
|
||
6 |
||
|
||
|
||
15. Mr Maunder Taylor expressed
his views, with reference to the subject property, on the four risk
factors identified in Sportelli: volatility, illiquidity,
deterioration and obsolescence. He said that property investors recognised
that prime properties were subject to less volatility than non-prime
properties. Similarly there was greater illiquidity in non-prime
properties because they were less attractive to mortgage finance. While in
so-called boom periods there was a ready supply of loan finance and a
favourable balance of buyers for all properties, in periods of bust there
was a less favourable balance of potential buyers, who were more conscious
of the quality of the property in which they were prepared to invest. The
freehold vacant possession value at any given valuation date merely
reflected that part of the short-term property cycle as it was then and
did not reflect the long-term risk profile. The greater volatility and
illiquidity of non-prime properties thus justified a higher risk
factor. |
||
|
||
16. On deterioration and
obsolescence, Mr Maunder Taylor’s view was that in prime areas there was a
greater interest on the part of property owners in preserving and
conserving character properties and maintaining them in terms of
accommodation layout, general appearance, updating services and similar
matters that constituted the main factors in obsolescence and
deterioration. He considered that the subject flats at Royston Court were
originally built to a non-prime standard, probably for letting-out, and
did not meet modern environmental standards. They were modest value flats
which did not compare well with new flats being built in the area. In his
view the obsolescence and deterioration risks for the property were higher
than for prime properties. |
||
|
||
17. Mr Maunder Taylor said that
in his opinion the market value of the flats at any point in time
reflected a relatively short-term expectation on the part of purchasers
and mortgagees. Their assumption was that there would be no significant
change in aspects of obsolescence or deterioration during their period of
ownership or loan, which they probably expected to be between about 10 and
20 years. Such value did not reflect the long-term view of the
hypothetical investor considering the reversion about 65 years after the
valuation date, and in his opinion the flats were likely to be obsolete by
the term date. |
||
|
||
18. Treating obsolescence only as
a risk factor was, Mr Maunder Taylor said, at odds with the approach in
valuations under the Leasehold Reform Act 1967. In such valuations, unless
a building was considered to be of good enough quality for a Haresign
addition (see Haresign v St John’s College, Oxford (1980) 255
EG 711) to be made, the section 15 ground rent was valued to perpetuity
and there was no calculation of the value of the ultimate reversion. Most
properties, with a 99-year lease from construction and the 50-year
statutory extension under the 1967 Act, were thus effectively regarded as
being obsolete after 149 years. The Royston Court properties, having been
built during the 1930s, would be about 135 years old at the term date, and
in his view investors would regard the property as being obsolete by that
date. No Haresign addition would fall to be
made. |
||
|
||
19. At some point in the future,
Mr Maunder Taylor said, a private developer would redevelop the site. That
point would come when the site value was perceived to be equivalent to or
greater than the aggregate value of the four flats plus acquisition,
planning and development costs. The rate at which prime properties in
prime locations moved towards this point of obsoleteness was, he said,
much slower than with modest suburban property such as Royston Court and
typical 1967 Act cases where no Haresign addition was made. For
this |
||
|
||
7 |
||
|
||
|
||
reason the risk factor for
deterioration and obsolescence must be greater for non-prime properties
than for prime properties, and this should be reflected in the deferment
rate. |
||
|
||
20. The argument
that the approach to obsolescence in Sportelli was at odds with
Lands Tribunal decisions under the 1967 Act was not a matter that had been
considered either in Sportelli itself or in subsequent Lands
Tribunal decisions, and it seemed sufficiently important for us to request
further evidence and submissions from both parties upon it. In his further
evidence Mr Maunder Taylor gave his understanding of four Lands Tribunal
decisions under the 1967 Act – Farr v Millersons Investments Ltd
(1971) 22 P & CR 1055, Haresign v St John’s College, Oxford
(1980) 255 EG 711, Windsor Life Assurance Co Ltd v Austin
[1996] 2 EGLR 169 and Marlodge (Monnow) Ltd’s Appeal
(LRA/28/2002).
21. Farr v
Millersons concerned a substantial semi-detached house on Wandsworth
Common, which had been built in the 1880s and was subject to a lease for
99 years granted in 1882. It had been divided into two flats. Mr Maunder
Taylor drew attention to the valuation practices that the Tribunal (R C
Walmsley FRICS) identified in the decision at 1060-1061:
“From the now considerable volume
of evidence that the tribunal has received on this matter a number of
valuation practices have emerged, each appropriate to different
circumstances, thus:
(a) Where
the subject house is likely to remain standing for the foreseeable future.
A practice of deriving its section 15 site value mainly by reference
to the whole premises as they stand; the site value being taken as a
proportion of this entirety value. The proportion normally adopted
(outside central London) varies, on the evidence, between one quarter and
one third, the actual proportion depending on such factors as the
cheapness or dearness of local land values, and the attributes of the site
looked at in the context of the entirety. In central London or in other
areas of highly priced residential land, the proportion adopted is
commonly higher, of the order of (plus or minus) 40%. This has been termed
‘the standing-house approach.’
(b) Where
the subject house is nearing the end of its economic life in the
foreseeable future. A practice of deriving its section 15 site value
mainly by reference to the prices of sites sold for development, or
redevelopment, for comparable uses. This has been termed ‘the cleared-site
approach.’
(c) Where
the subject house has an indeterminate economic life. A practice of
deriving its section 15 site value either by the cleared-site approach of
the standing-house approach, or by reference to what the property would be
worth if a new building were to be substituted for the existing building,
and then taking a proportion of that value or alternatively subtracting
the present day cost of putting up such a building. This latter has been
termed ‘the new-for-old approach.’ In the majority of cases a valuer will
decide to rely mainly on a particular one of these three approaches, but
will use one or both of the other two approaches as a
check.” |
||
|
||
8 |
||
|
||
|
||
22. The decision, Mr Maunder
Taylor said, concerned itself with the economic life of the building. It
did not actually use the expression “deterioration and obsolescence”, but,
he said, he had approached his evidence on the basis that that both
expressions essentially had similar or the same effect and meaning. After
considering the cleared site value and the entirety value, the Tribunal
had said that the site value of £5,250, which it had reached at on the
basis of the cleared site approach by reference to comparable
transactions, seemed to be supported by finding that that figure showed a
proportion of 40% of an entirety value which it had found to be just over
£13,000. Mr Maunder Taylor said that the Tribunal’s preferred approach of
the cleared site basis indicated that it considered the property to be
nearing the end of its economic life, but checked that approach against
the standing house approach for dependability. The landlord had not
provided evidence or made submissions about the ultimate reversion in 63
years’ time, possibly because it was too small, possibly because
obsolescence by that date had been accepted, or possibly because nobody
had thought about attempting to make such an addition. The Tribunal had
found that the entirety value as a house (rather than as flats) was
£10,000, so that it was obsolete for this purpose. What the Tribunal had
found, therefore, said Mr Maunder Taylor, was that at the end of the
original 99-year term the site value was 40% of the entirety value and
that at the end of the 50-year extension the site value was the entirety
value. |
||
|
||
23. In relation to
Haresign, which concerned a late Victorian 3-storey house in
Oxford, held under a 99-year lease from 1982, Mr Maunder Taylor noted that
there was no discussion about deterioration or obsolescence. In its
decision the Tribunal (V G Wellings QC) included in the price, in addition
to the capitalised ground rent for the residue of the term and the section
15 value, an amount for the reversion to the standing house value at the
end of the 50 years’ extension. The landlord’s valuer had said that in
most cases such an addition would be microscopically small but that in the
case of the subject house the amount would be material. The Member said
that he was driven to apply the valuer’s method of valuation because there
was no other evidence that would enable him to make a determination. Mr
Maunder Taylor said that that the case provided little or no background to
assist him. |
||
|
||
24. Windsor Life Assurance Co
Ltd v Austin concerned a semi-detached house in Redditch built in 1971
and with 77 years of a 99-year lease outstanding at the valuation date. Mr
Maunder Taylor noted that there was no evidence on deterioration and
obsolescence, and in view of the fact that the valuation date was in 1992
it might well be, he thought, that these were not particular thoughts in
the minds of the valuers. He drew attention to certain passages in the
decision of the Tribunal (M St J Hopper FRICS) that, he said, suggested
that variable risk rates should be taken in such cases as distinct from
the single universal risk rate adopted in
Sportelli. |
||
|
||
25. The Marlodge decision
also, Mr Maunder Taylor said, did not consider the economic life of the
building, and the Tribunal (P H Clarke FRICS) put the essential question
as “...not whether the subject property will still be standing 62 years
after the valuation date, but whether the purchaser in the hypothetical
sale envisaged in Section 9(1) of the 1967 Act would value the reversion
to standing house value?” Mr Maunder Taylor said that in his opinion and
experience the three approaches considered in Farr v Millersons for
1967 Act cases had been reduced to one approach based on the standing
house approach. The approaches had been developed for modest value houses
below certain rateable value limits, and it was not difficult to accept
that such houses were likely to have a limited expectation of economic
life. The |
||
|
||
9 |
||
|
||
|
||
1993 Act extended enfranchisement
to the whole range of houses and flats. For prime properties in prime
locations there was an expectation that the owners or occupiers would
maintain, upgrade and improve those properties over the long term. Such
characteristics were, however, rarely found in non-prime properties in
non-prime areas, so that deterioration and obsolescence was a much smaller
issue in relation to the former than the latter. |
||
|
||
26. Obsolescence, Mr Maunder
Taylor said, had a number of components. The appearance of a building
could come to be seen as old-fashioned or drab or even unpleasant. The
same would apply to its function, in terms of the usefulness and economy
of its services and its insulation. The occupiers of prime property could
be expected to be more demanding about the quality and upgrading of
services and installations than occupiers of non-prime property, so that
investors would pay higher prices (reflecting lower yield rates) for them.
Layout and location were other factors. Changes affecting the location,
such as transport links, the character of the area, conversion of houses
to multiple occupation, gentrification and employment opportunities,
could, if marginal, be reflected by adjusting the vacant possession value
but if substantial the result would tend to be redevelopment with a
different density, type and character of building. |
||
|
||
27. Mr Shapiro rejected the
contention that the Sportelli basic deferment rate should be
adjusted upwards to reflect a greater risk of obsolescence in the subject
property. There was no greater risk than in the case of The Holt, a
similar type of property in a similar suburban situation, or indeed
property within the PCL area. In contrast to The Holt, where the
Lands Tribunal found that the property was “tired and shabby and not built
to modern standards”, the LVT in the present case had made no such adverse
comment. Having regard to the full repairing nature of the leases there
was no reason to consider that the property would decay faster than the
millions of properties that were built throughout the country in the
1930s. The leaseholders, with significant capital and/or mortgages tied up
in the properties, would try to maintain the value of their investment. Mr
Shapiro said that he had had experience of houses being built in
Borehamwood immediately after the second world war with walls constructed
of 4 inch concrete slabs which were experimental and had been found to be
sub-standard as regards insulation and risk of rusting from reinforcing
rods. In such cases there might well be a higher risk of exposure to
depreciation and obsolescence. Royston Court, however, was of standard
construction. Indeed, there was a good argument to say that it was better
constructed than blocks of flats built during the 1950s and
1960s. |
||
|
||
28. While the internal layout was
not ideal, with the bathroom being accessed through the kitchen, Mr
Shapiro said, it could be improved if necessary. This was an indication of
the flexibility of the property and its capability of adaptation. It was
in an area where demand would continue to exist for the foreseeable
future. There was no reason from a physical point of view why the property
should not still be standing in 200 to 300 years’ time. It might well be
that the site value in future would exceed the total value of the existing
flats, but that would not be because the flats were obsolete in themselves
but would be most likely to arise from the planning system providing for
different densities. It would not be the obsolescence of the property that
would lead to its redevelopment but rising land
values. |
||
|
||
29. Mr Shapiro said that Mr
Maunder Taylor’s view that the building would be obsolete when the site
value for redevelopment was equal to or greater than the value of the
property |
||
|
||
10 |
||
|
||
|
||
standing on the site was based on
a misunderstanding of the concept of obsolescence. What Mr Maunder Taylor
was referring to was not functional obsolescence, since the building could
still be in use and would remain useful. What he was really saying was
that the building might be “value obsolete”, which applied to every
property; hence large parts of London and other cities, towns and villages
were being rebuilt from time to time. This did not mean that the reversion
to vacant possession value should be ignored, because the reversion would
in fact be to a higher figure if the site value exceeded the values of the
flats standing on the site. |
||
|
||
30. Mr Shapiro said that
deterioration did not feature pre-Sportelli as a factor in the
deferment rate. The distinguishing feature then had only been location. He
had himself said before the LVT in the present case that if it had not
been for the decision in Sportelli he would have agreed a deferment
rate of 7% or higher and that he had in similar cases agreed rates of 8 or
8.5% if hope value was considered separately. He and other valuers had
been looking at valuation in a traditional way because that was what LVTs
were doing. What Sportelli had done was to show that the perceived
wisdom of valuers, when forensically examined, was wrong. In relation to
the factors other than location identified in Sportelli as bearing
on the risk rate, Mr Shapiro did not accept that non-prime markets
suffered more in a downturn than prime markets and thus showed a greater
volatility, or that higher value properties were less difficult to sell:
if anything, the reverse was the case. Sometimes it was easier to sell low
value property than higher value property, and at other times it was the
other way about. There was no evidence of a lower growth rate in the
location under consideration. Mr Shapiro said that he could not see any
reason, therefore, having regard to all the factors that Sportelli
had identified as being relevant to the risk premium, for departing
from the Sportelli generic deferment rate of 5%. The arguments that
Mr Maunder Taylor was now advancing were advanced by him in his evidence
in The Holt and were rejected by the Tribunal, and Mr Shapiro found
support for his conclusion in the decision in that
case. |
||
|
||
31. Mr Shapiro considered the
four cases decided under the 1967 Act to which reference had been made. He
referred to the Tribunal’s summary in Farr v Millersons ((1971) 22
P & CR 1055 at 1059-1060) of the “generally recognised method of
approach” to valuations under the 1967 Act:
“The generally recognised method of approach is to adopt three
stages as follows:
Stage 1. To capitalise the
rent payable for the house and premises under the existing tenancy, for
the period of the unexpired term of that tenancy.
Stage 2. To estimate the
rent that would be payable for the house and premises at the expiration of
the original term, in accordance with section 15(2) – ‘the section 15
rent.’
Stage 3. To capitalise
this section 15 rent as if in perpetuity, deferred for the period of the
unexpired term of the existing tenancy; not seeking to quantify any
different rent that might become substituted at the expiration of
twenty-five tears from the original term date, and not quantifying
separately the value in reversion at the expiration of fifty years from
the original term date.” |
||
|
||
11 |
||
|
||
|
||
32. Mr Shapiro said that there
was no evidence before the Tribunal that this approach was potentially
incorrect, and both valuers proceeded on this basis, so that the
three-stage approach was not tested to show the effect on the value of the
reversion. The reason for this, he said, was that there was a general
valuers’ perception that after 60 years the YP in perpetuity multiplied by
the rent payable was equal to or greater than the YP for the term plus
reversion to full rental value. This theory was derived from commercial
valuations where the rent payable had to increase very significantly on
reversion to show any increase in value. It did not have regard to the
fact that two separate matters were being considered, namely that the rent
receivable was based on only 40% of the capital value and that there was a
reversion to 100% of that figure. Together with the term to reversion the
discount rate used was critical, so that using the 8% rate used by the
Tribunal the loss to the landlord was small, but using a 5% rate the loss
would have been significant. |
||
|
||
33. In Haresign, Mr
Shapiro said, the Tribunal accepted that the age of the house was no bar
to using the three-stage approach adopted by the landlords’ valuer and
that what was relevant was whether the reversion had substantial value
(and not whether the house was substantial, a matter that was not referred
to). What mattered was the term to reversion. In Haresign it was 53
years. Here, in the case of Royston Court, it was 65 years, not
significantly different, so that had the Tribunal been considering the 65
years Royston Court reversion it would have made a Haresign
addition. |
||
|
||
34. Mr Maunder Taylor’s
fundamental criticism of Sportelli was in essence that it imposed a
straitjacket on the valuation process, effectively replacing the judgment
of the valuer by a prescription based on the evidence of financial
experts. That is, we think, to misunderstand the position, certainly as it
has been arrived at following the Court of Appeal’s decision in that case.
The decision in Sportelli related to properties in prime central
London. In the Court of Appeal Carnwath LJ said this (at paragraph 102)
about properties outside the PCL area:
“The Tribunal’s later comments on
the significance of their guidance do not distinguish in terms between the
PCL area and other parts of London or the country. However, there must in
my view be an implicit distinction. The issues within the PCL were fully
examined in a fully contested dispute between directly interested parties.
The same cannot be said in respect of other areas. The judgment that the
same deferment rate should apply outside the PCL area was made, and could
only be made, on the evidence then available. That must leave the way open
to the possibility of further evidence being called by other parties in
other cases directly concerned with different areas. The deferment rate
adopted by the Tribunal will no doubt be the starting point; and their
conclusions on the methodology, including the limitations of market
evidence, are likely to remain valid. However, it is possible to envisage
other evidence being called, for example, on issues relevant to the risk
premium for residential property in different areas. That will be a matter
for those advising future parties, and for the tribunals, to consider as
such issues arise.” |
||
|
||
35. Thus evidence of valuers as
to whether a higher risk premium should be taken because of the features
of the property under consideration, including its location, is of
undoubted relevance, and if a tribunal is satisfied on the evidence before
it that such features justify the application of a higher deferment rate
then, of course, it ought to apply such higher rate. In determining
whether a higher rate is appropriate it will need to bear in mind the
considerations |
||
|
||
12 |
||
|
||
|
||
that led the Tribunal in
Sportelli to adopt the approach that it did, and the primary
question will always be whether there are particular features that are not
fully reflected in the vacant possession value and thus should be
reflected in a higher risk premium. Moreover – and this is a matter that
may not, or may not sufficiently, emerge from the Tribunal’s
post-Sportelli decisions – what matters is the view that the
market, properly informed on relevant factual matters, would take on such
features (the prospective movement of house prices in the area, for
instance, or the potential obsolescence of the property) in considering an
investment in the reversion. On this the expert opinion of the valuer is
likely to be important. |
||
|
||
36. One particular matter to
which Mr Maunder Taylor has drawn attention is the attitude of investors
to possible future variations in growth rates in different locations. It
may be that an expectation that over the term of the lease as a whole the
growth rate will not diverge significantly from the overall growth in
residential property prices, or the fact that evidence of historical
growth rates fail to establish any such divergence in the past, will be
insufficient for an investor to make no allowance for location. Indeed,
since the investor is likely to be concerned about the tradeability of his
investment (see Sportelli in the Lands Tribunal [2006] RVR 386 at
paragraph 76), what may be expected to happen in the very long term is not
the only matter that he is likely to take into account. (We would add that
for this reason illiquidity, to the extent that it is related to the need
for mortgage finance, as Mr Maunder Taylor suggested, could well affect
the current vacant possession value more than the value of the reversion).
What is suggested is that investors would approach differently purchases
of reversions in prime and non-prime areas and areas that could (but might
not) experience a rapid rise in prices in the shorter-term and those for
which there is no such apparent prospect. While we do not regard this
particular categorisation of those investors as any more than
illustrative, we accept that such differences could cause a variation in
the discount rate that each would see as appropriate to a particular
investment. Of course the possibility of variations in growth rates over
the shorter term is likely to be reflected at least to some extent (and
possibly fully) in the vacant possession value. But the purchaser of the
reversion, unlike the purchaser of the freehold with vacant possession who
will live in or let the property, is simply interested in capital
appreciation and will approach his purchase from that standpoint. We see
no reason on the evidence to think that non-prime property prices are in
general more volatile than prime properties in the course of a property
cycle, but the sort of particular differential movements that might occur
could, we accept, give rise to different perceptions of risk on the part
of investors. For reasons that we give later, however, we are not
persuaded on the evidence before us that a higher deferment rate is
justified in the present case, and we think it likely that any adjustment
made on this basis would in any event be relatively
small. |
||
|
||
37. The matter that we have just
addressed – the investor’s perception of risk in relation to growth rates
in different locations – is not one that appears to have arisen for
consideration in the Lands Tribunal decisions on the deferment rate in
areas outside PCL since its decision in Sportelli. There have been a
number of other decisions of the Tribunal since Sportelli. Two of
those decisions (Nicholson’s Appeal (LRA/29/2006, 8 January 2007,
unreported) and Eyre Estate (Trustees’) Appeal (LRA/145/2006, 16
February 2007, unreported) were unopposed appeals by the landlord and were
decided before the Court of Appeal’s decision in Sportelli. The
decisions contain no discussion of the matters with which we are now
concerned. In Ulterra Ltd v Glenbarr (RTE) Company Ltd
(LRA/149/2006, 17 November 2007, unreported) the Tribunal refused to
upset the LVT’s decision on the deferment rate (7% on flats in Reading)
because the appeal was by way of review and no evidence was advanced in
the |
||
|
||
13 |
||
|
||
|
||
appeal. In three other decisions,
on appeals conducted by rehearing, Hildron Finance Ltd v Greenhill
Hampstead Ltd (LRA/120/2006, 10 January 2008, unreported), Daejan
Investments Ltd v The Holt (Freehold) Ltd (LRA/133/2006, 2 May 2008,
unreported) and Lippe Cik v Chavda (LRA/111/2007, 7 August 2008,
unreported) location and obsolescence were matters
considered. |
||
|
||
38. Hildron Finance
concerned a block of flats in Hampstead, at the northern end of the
Fitzjohn/Netherhall Conservation Area, described by the Tribunal as a
prime residential area (although it concluded at paragraph 33 that, for
the purposes of applying the Sportelli guidance, the appeal
property was to be taken as falling outside the PCL). The property had
been built in the early 1930s. It was of multi-storey construction but,
because of the sloping site, parts were on three storeys and parts on
five. The property was generally of solid construction, although the top
floor accommodation was contained within a timber framed mansard roof,
with brick-built cross walls. There were a number of entrance
halls/staircase areas serving different parts of the block. The Tribunal
concluded (paragraph 35) that, to the extent that the flats were (as Mr
Maunder Taylor, giving evidence for the nominee purchaser, had suggested)
deficient in design, layout, services, facilities, fittings and finishes,
those factors would presumably be reflected in the vacant possession
value. It considered that the only factor that might have had a greater
effect on value at the end of the lease was the mainly timber construction
of the top floors, but it thought that a purchaser would not feel it to be
sufficiently significant to justify an increase in the deferment
rate. |
||
|
||
39. The Holt concerned a
three-storey block of flats constructed in about 1930 of brick and
concrete, standing in communal grounds in Morden. The common parts were
described as basic and shabby. The Tribunal concluded (paragraphs 85-87)
that the age, physical condition, design and construction of The Holt were
factors that were already accounted for in the price of the flats. The
price paid by owner occupiers was fairly representative of the
reversionary vacant possession value since the investor would not
necessarily have a materially different time horizon for holding his
investment; and if, as Mr Maunder Taylor had suggested, the hypothetical
investor held the investment for the long term, any increase in the risk
premium to allow for the investor’s exposure to deterioration and
obsolescence would be offset by a reduced exposure to the volatility and
illiquidity of the property market. |
||
|
||
40. In Lippe Cik, which
concerned two blocks of 1930s flats in Hounslow, the LVT adopted a
deferment rate of 6.5% on the basis of a number of particular factors that
it considered to have application. It did not appear that these factors
were supported before it in any expert evidence, and beyond identifying
the factors the LVT gave no indication as to why it considered that they
justified a higher deferment rate (see paragraph 30 of the Lands Tribunal
decision). Before the Lands Tribunal there was expert evidence only on the
part of the appellant landlord, and this was to the effect that a higher
deferment rate was not justified. Of the first of the factors that the LVT
had identified the first was the location of the property. The Lands
Tribunal said (paragraph 31) that the mere fact of location did not
self-evidently affect the deferment rate. Since the evidence before it did
not show that growth rates were lower or that volatility was greater for
flats in the particular outer London location than in the PCL area there
was no justification for taking a higher deferment rate. Other factors
(continuing litigation between landlord and tenants about services and
charges, “very poor tenants”, the poor external condition of the premises,
traffic on the A3006 Bath Road and a |
||
|
||
14 |
||
|
||
|
||
flanking access road and aircraft
noise) appeared to the Lands Tribunal to be pre-eminently matters that
would be fully reflected in the vacant possession
value. |
||
|
||
41. We accept Mr Shapiro’s
criticisms of Mr Maunder Taylor’s suggestion that, for deferment rate
purposes, a building is obsolete when it is worth more as a redevelopment
site than as a standing house. Assuming the existing building represents
the most valuable use of the property at the valuation date, the deferment
rate is applied to the value of the existing building. If there is a
possibility that the reversion will be to a higher (site) value, it seems
to us that this would make the investment more, not less attractive and
thus reduce the appropriate deferment rate. Mr Maunder Taylor made broadly
the same point in Hildron as he has in this appeal. The Tribunal in
that case rejected it on the basis that “obsolescence is concerned with
the risk that a building will decline, not that the value for another
purpose will increase.” We see no reason on the evidence before us to
disagree with that conclusion. |
||
|
||
42. Having considered the further
evidence and submissions that we asked for, we do not think that the cases
decided under section 9(1) of the 1967 Act suggest that a particular
approach to obsolescence or deterioration is appropriate in 1993 Act
valuations. Of the four cases to which such evidence and submissions were
addressed, it was only to Farr v Millersons that the appellant
sought to attach any real weight. But the three-stage approach there
referred to and the different treatment recognised for houses with varying
prospective economic lives were not the subject of express decision. The
Tribunal simply noted established valuation practices that had grown up in
these respects, and the appropriateness of them was not a matter of
disagreement between the parties. The difference between valuing the
ultimate reversion separately and not so valuing it would in most
instances have been extremely small in view of the values involved, the
deferment period and the higher deferment rates then taken; and the
perception of valuers, to which Mr Shapiro referred, that after 60 years
the YP in perpetuity multiplied by the rent payable was equal to or
greater than the YP for the term plus reversion to full rental value,
would have conditioned the approach. While the review of the section 9(1)
decisions was helpful, in the result we do not see that any assistance is
to be derived from them, nor, we would add, do we see any inconsistency
between Sportelli and the way in which section 9(1) valuations are
at present carried out. |
||
|
||
43. As far as the present case is
concerned we see no reason to conclude that the risks arising from
obsolescence are such as to justify an increase in the deferment rate. The
property has no particular features that would in our view differentiate
it in this respect from the generality of
properties. |
||
|
||
44. We derive no assistance from
the inadequately quantified and inconclusive survey of valuers that Mr
Maunder Taylor carried out, nor from the fact, if it is indeed the case,
that in a very few instances LVTs may not have followed the Sportelli
guidance, nor from the other matters adduced by Mr Maunder Taylor in
support of his contention that such guidance was wrong. We can see no
reason at all why he should feel compelled, as he says he does, by reasons
of professional conduct, to continue to advance valuations that are in
conflict with the Sportelli guidance. Indeed it would seem to us
contrary to a proper professional approach to do so, given the role of
such guidance as recognised by the Court of Appeal. We have derived very
limited assistance from his evidence because it was directed more as a
challenge to that guidance than to its application. |
||
|
||
15 |
||
|
||
|
||
45. We note moreover the
occasions when Mr Maunder Taylor, acting for landlords, has supported the
application of a Sportelli rate before LVTs. He produced some
extracts from copies of the reports and submissions that he had submitted
on those occasions. In the case of 8 Wetherby Place he was quite clearly
expressing an expert opinion in favour of the application of a
Sportelli rate and seeking to distinguish those cases in which he
had argued for a higher rate. In two other cases he had applied
Sportelli rates in the evidence that he had given. When acting as
advocate he had advanced arguments in favour of the application of
Sportelli rates. The format of his reports and submissions was
basically the same. Each was entitled either “Expert witness report of” or
“Statement of submission” of “B R Maunder Taylor, FRICS, MAE. Specialist
field: Chartered Surveyor and property valuer”. While Mr Maunder Taylor is
correct in pointing out the different roles of advocate and expert
witness, the fact is that, when acting for landlords, he presents both
evidence and submissions when holding himself out as a specialist valuer
and is willing to accept instructions to apply Sportelli rates,
supporting them as necessary (as in 8 Wetherby Place) with an expression
of expert opinion. |
||
|
||
46. In the present case there is
not before us any factual evidence (for instance the historic growth rates
in London boroughs) which in our view supports a higher deferment rate for
a property such as this. To the extent that we are asked to determine a
higher rate in the light of the considerations set out in paragraph 36
above simply on the basis of Mr Maunder Taylor’s expression of opinion we
decline to do so. In view of what we have just said, we do not think that
it would be right to attach such weight to his opinion as to make it
decisive. We are not satisfied, as we have said, that there is any
justification for an adjustment to the deferment rate in respect of
obsolescence. We therefore uphold the LVT’s determination of a rate of
5%. |
||
|
||
Hope Value |
||
|
||
47. In Sportelli
the House of Lords (Lord Hoffman dissenting) concluded that hope value
can be taken into account under paragraph 3 of Schedule 6, in so far as it
is attributable to the possibility of non-participating tenants wishing to
obtain new leases of their flats in the open-market (and not as of right
under Chapter II of Part I of the 1993 Act). In Sportelli in the
Lands Tribunal at paragraph 112 the conclusion was reached (“convincingly”
per Lord Neuberger of Abbotsbury in the House of Lords at paragraph 69)
that it was appropriate to allow for hope value by applying a lump sum to
the value of the reversion prior to the statutory marriage value
apportionment.
48. In his
supplemental report, Mr Maunder Taylor said that on the basis of the
calculation of a deferment rate of 8% (not reflecting hope value) for
which he had argued, there should be an addition for the two
non-participating flats of separately calculated hope value at 5% of
marriage value. His valuation is at Appendix 1. He said that he had been
instructed, following the House of Lords judgment, to review Lands
Tribunal decisions where hope value had been either considered or
determined, and to comment on whether it was apparent that any valuation
principles had been established. He had also been asked to give evidence
as to how a typical investor in the real-world marketplace factored hope
value into the price he would be prepared to pay for ground rent
investments, and to give examples of sales of the reversions of
non-participating flats to arms-length investors by nominee purchasers in
enfranchisement cases. |
||
|
||
16 |
||
|
||
|
||
49. The Lands Tribunal decisions
in which the question of hope value had been considered were: Becker
Properties v Garden Court NW8 Property Company Limited [1998] 1 EGLR
121, which accepted the possibility of hope value in principle, but
concluded on the facts that the particularly long (over 80 years)
unexpired term of the non-participating flats meant that the purchaser of
a reversion would pay nothing extra for the expectation of being able to
grant extended leases. Maryland Estates v Campana Court Limited
(LRA/21/2000, 10 April 2001) (Unreported) which held that a 69 year
term was too remote for hope value to be added to a premium otherwise
determined. Shulem B Association Limited’s Appeal [2001] 1 EGLR 105
found hope value at 15% of marriage value (applied to non-participating
flats only) with 60.75 years unexpired. In that appeal, where the lessee
was not represented, Mr Maunder Taylor said that the opinions expressed by
Mr Shapiro (who was acting for the freeholder) were based upon a purchase
by one of his clients in 1994 of a block of 34 maisonettes in Loughton,
Essex. He said that he thought that this was the same block as the one
upon which he had been instructed by the current freeholders to prepare a
valuation in July 2008. Land Registry records and information from
managing agents indicated the rate at which investors’ hope of selling
lease extensions have turned into reality in the intervening period. The
data indicated an average of around one property per year commencing with
the 61 years unexpired in 1994, up to 46 years unexpired in 2008. If this
rate were that which an investor could expect in the marketplace
generally, then in the case of Royston Court he would anticipate one lease
extension over the next 15 years (there being just 2 non-participating
flats). However, Mr Maunder Taylor said that in his experience the rate of
lease extensions in Loughton was uncharacteristically slow, and he would
normally expect an investor to anticipate a faster
rate. |
||
|
||
50. He said that, as was evident
from paragraph 22 of the Shulem B decision, Mr Shapiro’s valuation
of the term and reversion and the hope value element demonstrated hope
value at 13.81% of marriage value. However, those calculations were
directly and proportionately dependent upon the deferment rate that was
employed. The calculations, he said, would be unrecognisably different if
a 5% deferment rate were substituted. Indeed, the Member, N J Rose FRICS,
recorded at paragraph 23, that “Mr Shapiro accepted that an alternative
method of reflecting hope value would be to reduce the yield…in order to
arrive at a similar result to that which he had calculated, it would be
necessary to reduce the yield in the whole calculation from 9% to
6%.” |
||
|
||
51. In Blendcrown Limited v
The Church Commissioners for England [2004] 1 EGLR 143, which related
to a block of 80 flats where 15 were non-participating (and represented
17.2% of the aggregate value), hope value was determined at 5% of marriage
value on non-participating flats only with 46.5 years unexpired. In that
case, Mr Maunder Taylor had argued that investors would pay hope value
only if they were satisfied that there would be long lease applications in
the reasonably near future, and he reflected hope value in his yield,
saying that a specific addition was not justified on the evidence. He
pointed to the conclusions of the Member (P H Clarke FRICS), where he said
(at paragraph 77):
“77 ….hope value is by its nature
speculative, uncertain and incapable of precise assessment. It is the
value now with the chance of a future payment...”
and continued at paragraph 79: |
||
|
||
17 |
||
|
||
|
||
“79 As to the amount of this
value, precision is impossible. I cannot accept Mr Maunder Taylor’s view
that it is included in the yield of 7%. If I had accepted a 6% yield then
I might have been persuaded that this yield is low enough to reflect an
element of hope value. A yield of 7% is, however, too high for it to
reflect more than investment value. There should be a separate addition
for hope value. Mr Ford [the respondent freeholder’s expert] said that an
investor would pay 25% of the potential marriage value, representing the
hope of the prospect of extracting marriage value by lease extensions in
the short to medium term. I agree with Mr Ford’s approach but think that
25% is too optimistic in the circumstances of this case. In my view, a
purchaser, although including hope value in his price, would have been
more cautious and attributed only 5% of the possible marriage value of the
non-participating flats as hope value.” |
||
|
||
52. The decision in Tyndale
& Others v Kingsgarn Limited (LRA/1/2002, 17 July 2002)
(Unreported) also found, Mr Maunder Taylor said, 5% of marriage value and
in that instance there were 63 years unexpired on the non-participating
flats. He referred also to other cases, and concluded that, in the round,
an analysis of all of them failed to establish any certain valuation
principles. However, he said that they did suggest that there was a cut
off point at which the unexpired term of the lease was too remote for
investors to attribute any additional value; any addition for hope value
where it was justified was less than 50% of the marriage value to which a
landlord was entitled, and it must be accepted that the quantum of hope
value for non-participating flats was not a certain calculation based upon
a known income at a definite point in time. |
||
|
||
53. Mr Maunder Taylor said that
the typical ground-rent investor in the marketplace understood that, where
the unexpired term was very long, his return would be almost exclusively
income with no prospect of capital growth or profit within the foreseeable
future. Conversely, where the unexpired term was short, he would regard
income in nominal terms and would anticipate that virtually all of his
return would be in the form of either capital growth or capital profit. On
this basis, he said, it was clear that hope value was not something that
would be applicable irrespective of the unexpired length of the term, and
that view was also supported by the House of Lords judgment in
Sportelli (paragraph 63), and an observation in Arbib
(Arbib v Earl Cadogan [2005] 3 EGLR 139) at paragraph 169. It
was his professional opinion, based upon these analyses, that hope value
was of rapidly diminishing interest below an unexpired term of 35 years,
and would also be of no interest to the investor where that term is over
80 years. |
||
|
||
54. He also said that in his
view, as with the arguments relating to deferment rate, an investor would
view the PCL market differently to other locations in terms of hope value.
In PCL there was a ready market for relatively short leases (less than the
35-40 years, as noted in paragraph 63 of the House of Lords judgment in
Sportelli), whereas, in the suburbs and elsewhere, it was
comparatively rare to find unexpired leases as short as this. Thus the
expectation of investors in the suburbs was that lessees probably would
seek lease extensions, and in most cases before the lease fell below 50
years unexpired. Hence, in his opinion, there would be more interest from
an investor in an investment such as Royston Court (and hence more hope
value) than in a PCL flat with the same unexpired
term. |
||
|
||
18 |
||
|
||
|
||
55. Mr Maunder Taylor said that
the term and reversion method of valuation is a tool used by valuers to
arrive at a value for a given property after analysing and adjusting
comparable transactions. That was not, in his experience, how an investor
worked. In the no-Act world, whilst he could put a value on ground rent
income because the amount and term were known, assessment of capital
growth or gain could only be by way of intuitive judgement. For instance,
there was no certainty as to whether (if at all) he would be able to sell
a lease extension to non-participants, buy out the lessee or successfully
pursue forfeiture action. It was, of course, the very action of the
participating tenants that made them the most likely to seek early lease
extensions, and the non-participating tenants who were the least likely
to. Thus, he said, insofar as the investor’s offer reflected hope value,
that value would be directed far more to the participating tenants and
less towards the non-participants. |
||
|
||
56. Mr Maunder Taylor said that
in his opinion, in valuation terms, hope value and deferment rate were
inextricably linked, with one being dependent upon the other. They were
merely different labels for two parts of the same figure: the prospect of
capital growth or gain. He said that this view was supported by the
Tribunal’s findings in Shulem B and Blendcrown, as well as
in his analysis of market results. In general terms, outside the PCL area,
investors would not make a purchase at a 5% deferment rate plus something
extra for hope value. In this case, not only would an investor not
contemplate purchasing the freehold reversion at a 5% deferment rate, but
also there was no margin out of what he would pay for the prospects of
capital growth unless the deferment rate were lifted to a much higher
level – as was considered in Shulem B. Quantifying hope value as a
separate figure was a product of the way in which valuations under the Act
had developed, and the exercise was particularly difficult in the
hypothetical no-Act world marketplace. He said that it seemed to him that
the consequence of the House of Lords judgment in Sportelli was
that it was accepted that the investor paid hope value:
a. in
respect of participating flats as part of the marriage value (with it
therefore being excluded from the term and reversion calculation),
and
b. for the
non-participating flats, it being now recognised that hope value is
payable and, there no longer being an assumption that the purchaser is
only investing for the reversion, with the valuation principles having
changed. |
||
|
||
57. In summary, Mr Maunder Taylor
said that it was his opinion that the Royston Court valuation should be
calculated at an 8% deferment rate (not reflecting hope value), with an
addition for the non-participating flats of separately calculated hope
value at 5% of marriage value. |
||
|
||
58. Mr Shapiro produced a revised
valuation showing an adjusted premium of £45,482 (Appendix 2). He said
that he had not amended any of the constituent parts of the LVT’s
valuation, other than to include hope value at 20%. In his view, there was
no reason to depart from the opinions that he had expressed before the
Tribunal when he given evidence for the tenant in Shulem B. There,
he had argued for 25% of marriage value, but he acknowledged that the
Tribunal decided that that was too much and determined hope value on the
non-participating flat at 15%. In his report to the Tribunal in that case
he had said: |
||
|
||
19 |
||
|
||
|
||
“7.5.1 With regard to the
non-participating flat, the price to be paid to the freeholder is the
price at which the property would sell in the open market. I believe that
this price is made up of the term and reversion together with the
expectation of a sale of a lease extension, i.e. hope value. The need for
a lease extension is clearly demonstrated by the market and hence the
transactions relating to numbers 11 and 26 Westmere Drive. Even if there
is a market for a lease of 60.75 years, the market conditions for this
lease will become increasingly difficult as the lease reduces in length….
In 1994 my client paid approximately 13.81% of the marriage value as hope
value. This was shortly after the 1993 Act was passed and the level of
premium which would be determined or agreed was therefore uncertain as was
the potential level of activity. The position is now much more certain and
hence I believe that a purchaser in the market for the investment today
would pay a higher share of marriage value to reflect this future gain. In
my opinion, in a lease which is wasting as rapidly as this one, the amount
which an investor would pay in the market for the investment would be the
investment value plus half of the marriage value.
7.5.2 It will be appreciated from
the above that if the non-participating lessee was to require a lease
extension immediately then the freeholder will have almost doubled his
money. If the lease extension is not required for some time then the
underlying increase in value will be even greater, because the term of the
lease will be shorter and the values will be greater.”
He went on to produce his valuation, and
concluded:
“7.5.2.1 An alternative way of
reflecting hope value would be to reduce the yield. The Leasehold
Valuation Tribunal believe that this could be done by reducing the yield
from 13% to 11%. On their calculation the collective enfranchisement price
was therefore £14,057. If the yield had been 13% the price would have been
£13,792 and therefore the additional price for the hope value was
calculated at £265. In view of the fact that half the marriage value in
one flat on the Tribunal’s figures was £2,194, this is an unrealistic
assessment, therefore the yield differential is insufficient. In order to
arrive at a similar result to that which I have calculated it would be
necessary to reduce the yield in the whole calculation from 9% to
6%.” |
||
|
||
59. Mr Shapiro said that he was
aware that the Tribunal has adopted different percentages in other
decisions, and he accepted that there could be no hard and fast rule as to
the appropriate amount. However, he said he could not accept the LVT’s
decision in Gesso Properties (BVI) Ltd v SCMLLA Ltd (LRA/13/2003, 1
March 2004) (Unreported), as such a figure (5%) was only a nominal
addition which was within normal valuation tolerances and would thus be
incapable of being assessed as a separate number from any analysis of
sales. Clearly, he said, the percentage must be less than 50% because a
purchaser in the market would require a profit to allow for the
possibility that the lessees might seek to obtain extensions immediately
after purchase. However, the hypothetical purchaser did have to cover his
costs of acquisition and allow for risks together with interest on capital
until such time as extensions were sought. Thus, the percentage did have
to be significant and, for the reasons that he gave, he considered that 5%
was not significant. In his view, although it could not be supported by
any further evidence, 20% of marriage value was an appropriate figure to
adopt. |
||
|
||
20 |
||
|
||
|
||
60. In cross-examination Mr
Shapiro accepted that where tenants were not participating in the
collective enfranchisement that was an indication that they were not, at
that time, interested in claiming lease extensions. However, he said that
what was relevant was the expectation that at some time in the future,
often at the point the lessee decided that he wished to sell, he would
decide to apply for extension. He said that, in his experience, it was not
normal for investment purchasers to make inquiries of non-participating
tenants. They would apply their experience in assessing how many and how
often such applications could be anticipated. |
||
|
||
61. Mr Radevsky submitted, in the
light of the preference as to the treatment of hope value on
non-participating flats expressed by Lord Neuberger at paragraph 69 of the
House of Lords judgment in Sportelli, that the Tribunal should
prefer Mr Shapiro’s 20% of marriage value as the bare minimum of lessees
were participating, thereby keeping marriage value low. Mr Maunder
Taylor’s argument for 5% based largely on Blendcrown was, he said,
self defeating. In that case there were two important factors to be
considered: the relatively short unexpired terms and the proportion of
non-participating flats (representing 17.2% of the aggregate value). In
the present case there was a much longer period during which the
anticipated marriage value would rise and the proportion of participating
flats was 50% both in terms of number and value. Accordingly, it stood to
reason that the that the hope value to be applied here must be more than
the 5% determined in that case and sought here by Mr Maunder Taylor.
Furthermore Mr Maunder Taylor’s 5% was even smaller than the figures that
he used to advise his clients in two of the properties that he had
referred to in his evidence: Avon Terrace and Broomfield
Avenue. |
||
|
||
62. Both experts relied upon
previous decisions of the Lands Tribunal that had taken hope value at
between 5% and 20% of marriage value, with Mr Shapiro considering the
upper level to be appropriate, and Mr Maunder Taylor opting for the lowest
figure. Considerable care needs to be exercised before any weight is
attached to specific percentages adopted in other cases both for the
reasons expressed by the Member in Blendcrown, (see the passages
reproduced at paragraph 51 above) and because, in the light of
Sportelli, the correct approach now is to approach hope value and
the deferment quite separately. Hope value is not a matter to be taken
into account in the deferment rate, and the deferment rate has no
influence on what the appropriate allowance for hope value should
be. |
||
|
||
63. There are in our judgment two
particular valuation matters to be borne in mind in the determination of
hope value. Firstly, it is likely to be greater if the proportion of
non-participating flats is relatively large. Secondly, it will be lower if
the unexpired terms are particularly long. In the present case the
unexpired terms of the leases are 65.37 years and 50% of the
lessees are non-participators. Taking all matters into account, and
bearing in mind the essentially speculative nature of hope value, we
conclude that hope value in this case may be expressed as 10% of marriage
value. The Tribunal’s valuation is at Appendix 3. |
||
|
||
Summary |
||
|
||
64. The two issues are determined
as follows: deferment rate 5%; hope value relating to the
non-participating flats 10% of marriage value. The price to be paid for
the enfranchisement is £42,883. |
||
|
||
21 |
||
|
||
|
||
Dated 7 September 2009 |
||
|
||
George Bartlett QC, President |
||
|
||
Paul Francis FRICS |
||
|
||
22 |
||
|
||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Appendix 1 LRA/82/2007
Appellant’s valuation
Report of: B R Maunder
Taylor, FRICS, MAE
Specialist Field: Chartered Surveyor and Property
Valuer
On behalf of: Amanda Jane Culley
(Applicant)
Prepared for: The Lands
Tribunal |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Four flats each leased for 99
years from 24 June 1972
Flat 6 at a fixed ground rent of
£25 p.a.
Flat 5 pays £25/£50/£75 p.a.
rising every 33 years
Flats 7 & 8 each pay
£20/£35/£50 p.a. rising every 33 years
Flats 7/8
participating
Flats 5 & 8 with one bedroom,
Flats 6 and 7 with two bedrooms
Valuation Date: 8 February
2006
Capitalisation rate determined:
7% p .a.
Values determined
2-beds: long lease £160,000 each;
existing lease £139,200 each
1-bed: long lease £145,000 each;
existing lease £126,150 each |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
23 |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Report of: B R Maunder Taylor,
FRICS, MAE SpecialistField: Chartered Surveyor and Property Valuer On
behalf of: Amanda Jane Culley (Applicant) Prepared for: The Lands
Tribunal |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
24 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
LRA/82/2007 APPENDIX
2 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Respondent’s Valuation |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
5-8 Royston Court, North View, Eastcote, Middlesex, HA5
1PG |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
65.37 yrs |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Value of share of Freehold
Value of existing lease
Value of Freehold current
interest
Rent reserved |
£305,000 |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
87.00% £265,350 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
£886 |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
£145 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
£12,565 |
£13,597 |
£278,947 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Marriage Value
Freehold Price for flats
(2) Non Participating Lessees - Flats 5 & 6 Value of share of
Freehold Value of existing lease |
£26,053
50% £13,026
£13,597 |
£26,624 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
£305,000 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
87.00% £265,350 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
25 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||
Value of Freehold current
interest |
||
|
||
Rent reserved
£ 75.00
YP to 1st review
12.6602 £950
Reversion to
£100.00
YP to reversion
12.779
x PV of £1 to 2nd review
0.1138 1.4541
£145
Reversion to VP value
£305,000
x PV of £1 to Reversion
0.0412 £12,565 £13,660
£279,010 |
||
|
||
£25,990 Hope Value
20%
£ 5,198
£13,660
£18,858
£45,482 |
||
|
||
26 |
||
|
||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Lands Tribunal’s Valuation |
LRA/82/2007 APPENDIX
3 |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
5-8 Royston Court, North View, Eastcote, Middlesex, HA5
1PG |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
INPUT INFORMATION |
Rent to: |
25/03/2038 23/06/2071 32.12
33.25 |
Extended lease
values |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
65.37 yrs |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Participants |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Value of share of Freehold
Value of existing lease |
£305,000 |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
87.00% £265,350 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
£886 |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
£145 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
£12,565 |
£13,597 |
£278,947 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Marriage Value
Freehold Price for flats
(2) Non Participating Lessees - Flats 5 & 6 Value of share of
Freehold Value of existing lease |
£26,053
50% £13,026
£13,597 |
£26,624 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
£305,000 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
87.00% £265,350 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
27 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||
Value of Freehold current
interest |
||
|
||
Rent reserved
£ 75.00
YP to 1st review
12.6602 £950
Reversion to
£100.00
YP to reversion
12.779
x PV of £1 to 2nd review
0.1138 1.4541
£145
Reversion to VP value
£305,000
x PV of £1 to Reversion
0.0412 £12,565 £13,660
£279,010 |
||
|
||
£25,990 Hope Value
10%
£ 2,599
£13,660
£16,259
£42,883 |
||
|
||
28 |
||
|
||